<SPAN name="toc23" id="toc23"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="pdf24" id="pdf24"></SPAN>
<h2><span>Chapter III. Of Capital.</span></h2>
<SPAN name="toc25" id="toc25"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 1. Capital is Wealth Appropriated to Reproductive Employment.</span></h3>
<p>
It has been seen in the preceding chapters that besides
the primary and universal requisites of production,
labor and natural agents, there is another requisite without
which no productive operations beyond the rude and scanty
beginnings of primitive industry are possible—namely, a
stock, previously accumulated, of the products of former labor.
This accumulated stock of the produce of labor is
termed Capital. What capital does for production is, to
afford the shelter, protection, tools, and materials which the
work requires, and to feed and otherwise maintain the laborers
during the process. These are the services which present
labor requires from past, and from the produce of past,
labor. Whatever things are destined for this use—destined
to supply productive labor with these various prerequisites—are
Capital.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
Professor Fawcett, </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Manual</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> (chap. ii), says: </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Since the
laborer must be fed by previously accumulated food, ... some
of the results of past labor are required to be set aside to sustain
the laborer while producing. The third requisite of production,
therefore, is a fund reserved from consumption, and
devoted to sustain those engaged in future production....
Capital is not confined to the food which feeds the laborers,
but includes machinery, buildings, and, in fact, every product
due to man's labor which can be applied to assist his industry</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">
(chap. iv). General Walker (</span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Political Economy,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> pages 68-70)
defines capital as that portion of wealth (excluding unimproved
land and natural agents) which is employed in the
production of new forms of wealth. Henry George (</span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Progress
and Poverty,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> page 41) returns to Adam Smith's definition:
</span>
<span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">That part of a man's stock which he expects to yield
him a revenue is called his capital.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> Cherbuliez (</span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Précis,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">
page 70) points out the increasing interdependence of industrial
operations as society increases in wealth, and that there is not
a single industry which does not demand the use of products
obtained by previous labor. </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">These auxiliary products accumulated
with a view to the production to which they are subservient</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">
form what is called capital. Carey (</span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Social Science,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">
iii, page 48) regards as capital all things which in any
way form the machinery by which society obtains wealth.
Roscher's definition is, </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Every product laid by for purposes
of further production.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> (</span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Political Economy,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> section 42.)
By some, labor is regarded as capital.</span><SPAN id="noteref_104" name="noteref_104" href="#note_104"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">104</span></span></SPAN>
<p>
A manufacturer, for example, has one part of his capital
in the form of buildings, fitted and destined for carrying on
this branch of manufacture. Another part he has in the
form of machinery. A third consists, if he be a spinner, of
raw cotton, flax, or wool; if a weaver, of flaxen, woolen,
silk, or cotton thread; and the like, according to the nature
of the manufacture. Food and clothing for his operatives
it is not the custom of the present age that he should directly
provide; and few capitalists, except the producers of food
or clothing, have any portion worth mentioning of their capital
in that shape. Instead of this, each capitalist has money,
which he pays to his work-people, and so enables them to
supply themselves. What, then, is his capital? Precisely
that part of his possessions, whatever it be, which he designs
to employ in carrying on fresh production. It is of
no consequence that a part, or even the whole of it, is in a
form in which it can not directly supply the wants of laborers.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
Care should be taken to distinguish between wealth,
capital, and money. Capital may be succinctly defined as
</span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">saved wealth devoted to reproduction</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%">, and the relations of the
three terms mentioned may be illustrated by the following
figure: The area of the circle, A, represents the wealth of a
country; the area of the inscribed circle, B, the quantity out
of the whole wealth which is saved and devoted to reproduction
and called capital. But money is only one part of capital,
as shown by the area of circle C. Wherefore, it can be plainly
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
seen that not all capital, B, is money; that not all wealth, A,
is capital, although all capital is necessarily wealth as included
within it. It is not always understood that
money is merely a convenient article by
which other forms of wealth are exchanged
against each other, and that a man may
have capital without ever having any actual
money in his possession. In times of
commercial depression, that which is capital
to-day may not to-morrow satisfy any
desires (i.e., not be in demand), and so
for the time it may, so to speak, drop entirely
out of our circles above. For the
moment, not having an exchange value, it can not be wealth,
and so can the less be capital.
</span>
<p></p>
<ANTIMG src="images/capital-circle.png" width-obs="369" height-obs="411" alt="Illustration. Outer circle A, enclosing inner circle B, with small circle C overlapping edge of circle B." />
<p>
Suppose, for instance, that the capitalist is a hardware
manufacturer, and that his stock in trade, over and above
his machinery, consists at present wholly in iron goods.
Iron goods can not feed laborers. Nevertheless, by a mere
change of the destination of the iron goods, he can cause
laborers to be fed. Suppose that [the capitalist changed into
wages what he had before spent] in buying plate and jewels;
and, in order to render the effect perceptible, let us suppose
that the change takes place on a considerable scale, and that
a large sum is diverted from buying plate and jewels to employing
productive laborers, whom we shall suppose to have
been previously, like the Irish peasantry, only half employed
and half fed. The laborers, on receiving their increased
wages, will not lay them out in plate and jewels, but in food.
There is not, however, additional food in the country; nor
any unproductive laborers or animals, as in the former case,
whose food is set free for productive purposes. Food will
therefore be imported if possible; if not possible, the laborers
will remain for a season on their short allowance: but
the consequence of this change in the demand for commodities,
occasioned by the change in the expenditure of capitalists
from unproductive to productive, is that next year more
food will be produced, and less plate and jewelry. So that
again, without having had anything to do with the food of
the laborers directly, the conversion by individuals of a portion
of their property, no matter of what sort, from an unproductive
destination to a productive, has had the effect of
causing more food to be appropriated to the consumption of
productive laborers. The distinction, then, between Capital
and Not-capital, does not lie in the kind of commodities, but
in the mind of the capitalist—in his will to employ them for
one purpose rather than another; and all property, however
ill adapted in itself for the use of laborers, is a part of capital,
so soon as it, or the value to be received from it, is set
apart for productive reinvestment.</p>
<SPAN name="toc26" id="toc26"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 2. More Capital Devoted to Production than Actually Employed in it.</span></h3>
<p>
As whatever of the produce of the country is devoted
to production is capital, so, conversely, the whole of
the capital of the country is devoted to production. This
second proposition, however, must be taken with some limitations
and explanations. (1) A fund may be seeking for
productive employment, and find none adapted to the inclinations
of its possessor: it then is capital still, but unemployed
capital. (2) Or the stock may consist of unsold goods, not
susceptible of direct application to productive uses, and not,
at the moment, marketable: these, until sold, are in the condition
of unemployed capital.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
This is not an important distinction. The goods are doubtless
marketable at some price, if offered low enough. If no
one wants them, then, by definition, they are not wealth so
long as that condition exists.
</span>
<p>
(3) [Or] suppose that the Government lays a tax on the
production in one of its earlier stages, as, for instance, by taxing
the material. The manufacturer has to advance the tax,
before commencing the manufacture, and is therefore under
a necessity of having a larger accumulated fund than is required
for, or is actually employed in, the production which
he carries on. He must have a larger capital to maintain the
same quantity of productive labor; or (what is equivalent)
with a given capital he maintains less labor. (4) For another
example: a farmer may enter on his farm at such a time of
the year that he may be required to pay one, two, or even
three quarters' rent before obtaining any return from the
produce. This, therefore, must be paid out of his capital.</p>
<p>
(5) Finally, that large portion of the productive capital of a
country which is employed in paying the wages and salaries
of laborers, evidently is not, all of it, strictly and indispensably
necessary for production. As much of it as exceeds the
actual necessaries of life and health (an excess which in the
case of skilled laborers is usually considerable) is not expended
in supporting labor, but in remunerating it, and the
laborers could wait for this part of their remuneration until
the production is completed.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
The previous accumulation of commodities requisite for
production must inevitably be large enough to cover necessaries,
but need not be more, if the laborer is willing to wait
for the additional amount of his wages (the amount of his unproductive
consumption) until the completion of the industrial
operation. In fact, however, the accumulation must be sufficient
to pay the laborer all his wages from week to week, by
force of custom (wherever there is any considerable division of
labor), and also sufficient to purchase tools and materials. The
various elements of capital are materials, instruments, and subsistence,
giving </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">instruments</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> its wide signification which
includes money (the tool of exchange), and other necessary
appliances of each special kind of production.
</span>
<p>
In truth, it is only after an abundant capital had already
been accumulated that the practice of paying in advance any
remuneration of labor beyond a bare subsistence could possibly
have arisen: since whatever is so paid is not really
applied to production, but to the unproductive consumption
of productive laborers, indicating a fund for production sufficiently
ample to admit of habitually diverting a part of it
to a mere convenience.</p>
<p>
It will be observed that I have assumed that the laborers
are always subsisted from capital:<SPAN id="noteref_105" name="noteref_105" href="#note_105"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">105</span></span></SPAN> and this is obviously
the fact, though the capital need not necessarily be furnished
by a person called a capitalist.</p>
<p>
The peasant does not subsist this year on the produce
of this year's harvest, but on that of the last. The artisan
is not living on the proceeds of the work he has in hand,
but on those of work previously executed and disposed of.
Each is supported by a small capital of his own, which he
periodically replaces from the produce of his labor. The
large capitalist is, in like manner, maintained from funds
provided in advance.</p>
<SPAN name="toc27" id="toc27"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 3. Examination of Cases Illustrative of the Idea of Capital.</span></h3>
<p>
That which is virtually capital to the individual is or
is not capital to the nation, according as the fund which by
the supposition he has not dissipated has or has not been
dissipated by somebody else.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
Let the reader consider, in the four following suppositions,
whether or not the given capital has wholly dropped out of the
circle in the diagram, page </span><SPAN href="#Pg067" class="tei tei-ref"><span style="font-size: 90%">67</span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%">. In (3) and (4) the wealth is
entirely dissipated; as it can not longer be in circle A, it can
not, of course, be in circle B.
</span>
<p>
(1.) For example, let property of the value of ten thousand
pounds, belonging to A, be lent to B, a farmer or manufacturer,
and employed profitably in B's occupation. It is as
much capital as if it belonged to B. A is really a farmer
or manufacturer, not personally, but in respect of his property.
Capital worth ten thousand pounds is employed in
production—in maintaining laborers and providing tools and
materials—which capital belongs to A, while B takes the
trouble of employing it, and receives for his remuneration
the difference between the profit which it yields and the interest
he pays to A. This is the simplest case.</p>
<p>
(2.) Suppose next that A's ten thousand pounds, instead
of being lent to B, are lent on mortgage to C, a landed
proprietor, by whom they are employed in improving the
productive powers of his estate, by fencing, draining,
road-making, or permanent manures. This is productive
employment. The ten thousand pounds are sunk, but not
dissipated. They yield a permanent return; the land now
affords an increase of produce, sufficient in a few years, if
the outlay has been judicious, to replace the amount, and in
time to multiply it manifold. Here, then, is a value of ten
thousand pounds, employed in increasing the produce of the
country. This constitutes a capital, for which C, if he lets
his land, receives the returns in the nominal form of increased
rent; and the mortgage entitles A to receive from
these returns, in the shape of interest, such annual sum as
has been agreed on.</p>
<p>
(3.) Suppose, however, that C, the borrowing landlord, is
a spendthrift, who burdens his land not to increase his fortune
but to squander it, expending the amount in equipages
and entertainments. In a year or two it is dissipated, and
without return. A is as rich as before; he has no longer
his ten thousand pounds, but he has a lien on the land,
which he could still sell for that amount. C, however, is ten
thousand pounds poorer than formerly; and nobody is richer.
It may be said that those are richer who have made profit
out of the money while it was being spent. No doubt if C
lost it by gaming, or was cheated of it by his servants, that
is a mere transfer, not a destruction, and those who have
gained the amount may employ it productively. But if C
has received the fair value for his expenditure in articles of
subsistence or luxury, which he has consumed on himself, or
by means of his servants or guests, these articles have ceased
to exist, and nothing has been produced to replace them:
while if the same sum had been employed in farming or
manufacturing, the consumption which would have taken
place would have been more than balanced at the end of the
year by new products, created by the labor of those who
would in that case have been the consumers. By C's prodigality,
that which would have been consumed with a return
is consumed without return. C's tradesmen may have made
a profit during the process; but, if the capital had been expended
productively, an equivalent profit would have been
made by builders, fencers, tool-makers, and the tradespeople
who supply the consumption of the laboring-classes;
while, at the expiration of the time (to say nothing of an
increase), C would have had the ten thousand pounds or
its value replaced to him, which now he has not. There is,
therefore, on the general result, a difference, to the disadvantage
of the community, of at least ten thousand pounds,
being the amount of C's unproductive expenditure. To A,
the difference is not material, since his income is secured to
him, and while the security is good, and the market rate of
interest the same, he can always sell the mortgage at its
original value. To A, therefore, the lien of ten thousand
pounds on C's estate is virtually a capital of that amount;
but is it so in reference to the community? It is not. A
had a capital of ten thousand pounds, but this has been extinguished—dissipated
and destroyed by C's prodigality. A
now receives his income, not from the produce of his capital,
but from some other source of income belonging to C, probably
from the rent of his land, that is, from payments made
to him by farmers out of the produce of <em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-style: italic">their</span></em> capital.</p>
<p>
(4.) Let us now vary the hypothesis still further, and
suppose that the money is borrowed, not by a landlord, but
by the state. A lends his capital to Government to carry
on a war: he buys from the state what are called government
securities; that is, obligations on the Government to
pay a certain annual income. If the Government employed
the money in making a railroad, this might be a productive
employment, and A's property would still be used as capital;
but since it is employed in war, that is, in the pay of officers
and soldiers who produce nothing, and in destroying a quantity
of gunpowder and bullets without return, the Government
is in the situation of C, the spendthrift landlord, and
A's ten thousand pounds are so much national capital which
once existed, but exists no longer—virtually thrown into the
sea, as wealth or production is concerned; though for
other reasons the employment of it may have been justifiable.
A's subsequent income is derived, not from the produce
of his own capital, but from taxes drawn from the produce
of the remaining capital of the community; to whom
his capital is not yielding any return, to indemnify them for
the payment; it is all lost and gone, and what he now possesses
is a claim on the returns to other people's capital
and industry.</p>
<p>
The breach in the capital of the country was made when
the Government spent A's money: whereby a value of ten
thousand pounds was withdrawn or withheld from productive
employment, placed in the fund for unproductive consumption,
and destroyed without equivalent.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
The United States had borrowed in the late civil war, by August
31, 1865, $2,845,907,626; and, to June 30, 1881, the Government
had paid in interest on its bonds, </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">from taxes drawn
from the produce of the remaining capital,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> $1,270,596,784,
as an income to bondholders. From this can be seen the
enormous waste of wealth to the United States during the war,
and consequently the less existing capital to-day in this country;
since, under the same inducements to save, the smaller the
outside circle (wealth), the less the inside circle (capital) must
be.
</span>
<hr class="page" />
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />