<SPAN name="toc102" id="toc102"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="pdf103" id="pdf103"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="Book_II_Chapter_V" id="Book_II_Chapter_V" class="tei tei-anchor"></SPAN>
<h2><span>Chapter V. Of Profits.</span></h2>
<SPAN name="toc104" id="toc104"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="Book_II_Chapter_V_Section_1" id="Book_II_Chapter_V_Section_1" class="tei tei-anchor"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 1. Profits include Interest and Risk; but, correctly speaking, do not include Wages of Superintendence.</span></h3>
<p>
Having treated of the laborer's share of the produce,
we next proceed to the share of the capitalist; the profits of
capital or stock; the gains of the person who advances the
expenses of production—who, from funds in his possession,
pays the wages of the laborers, or supports them during the
work; who supplies the requisite buildings, materials, and
tools or machinery; and to whom, by the usual terms of the
contract, the produce belongs, to be disposed of at his pleasure.
After indemnifying him for his outlay, there commonly
remains a surplus, which is his profit; the net income
from his capital [and skill]; the amount which he can afford
to expend in necessaries or pleasures, or from which by further
saving he can add to his wealth.</p>
<p>
As the wages of the laborer are the remuneration of labor,
so [a part of] the profits of the capitalist are properly,
according to Mr. Senior's well-chosen expression, the remuneration
of abstinence. They are what he gains by forbearing
to consume his capital for his own uses, and allowing it
to be consumed by productive laborers for their uses. For
this forbearance he requires a recompense.</p>
<p>
Of the gains, however, which the possession of a capital
enables a person to make, (1) a part only is properly an
equivalent for the use of the capital itself; namely, as much
as a solvent person would be willing to pay for the loan of it.
This, which as everybody knows is called interest, is all that
a person is enabled to get by merely abstaining from the
immediate consumption of his capital, and allowing it to be
used for productive purposes by others. The remuneration
which is obtained in any country for mere abstinence is
measured by the current rate of interest on the best security;
such security as precludes any appreciable chance of losing
the principal. What a person expects to gain, who superintends
the employment of his own capital, is always more, and
generally much more, than this. The rate of profit greatly
exceeds the rate of interest. (2.) The surplus is partly compensation
for risk. By lending his capital on unexceptionable
security he runs little or no risk. But if he embarks in
business on his own account, he always exposes his capital to
some, and in many cases to very great, danger of partial or
total loss. For this danger he must be compensated, otherwise
he will not incur it. (3.) He must likewise be remunerated
for the devotion of his time and labor. The control of
the operations of industry usually belongs to the person who
supplies the whole or the greatest part of the funds by which
they are carried on, and who, according to the ordinary arrangement,
is either alone interested, or is the person most
interested (at least directly), in the result. To exercise this
control with efficiency, if the concern is large and complicated,
requires great assiduity, and often no ordinary skill.
This assiduity and skill must be remunerated.</p>
<p>
The gross profits from capital, the gains returned to those
who supply the funds for production, must suffice for these
three purposes; and the three parts into which profit may
be considered as resolving itself may be described respectively
as interest, insurance, and wages of superintendence.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
Inasmuch as risk is the cause affecting the rate of interest,
it would be much simpler to consider the whole reward for abstinence
as interest, the rate of which is affected by the risk;
and to carefully exclude from the profits of capital the payment
for </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">assiduity and skill,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> which is distinctly wages of labor.
The </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">wages of superintendence,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> as every one on a moment's
reflection must admit, have no necessary connection whatever
with the possession of capital. The thing with which the laborer
is occupied does not give the reason for associating his
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
wages with the name of that thing; because a highly-qualified
manager supervises the operations of capital, it does not follow
that he has capital, or should be regarded as being paid for the
possession of capital. The man who shovels ashes is not paid
wages of ashes, any more than a man who superintends other
people's capital is paid the reward of capital. The payment
for services, in the one case as in the other, depends upon the
skill of the manager, just as it does with an ordinary mechanic,
rising or falling with his fitness for the peculiar work. Skill
as a manager is the cause; the amount of the remuneration is
the consequence. If so, then the wages of superintendence
have no logical connection, in the economic sense, with capital
as the thing which determines the amount of its reward,
any more than it affects the wages of any and all labor. The
payment for the use of capital, simply as capital, may be seen
by the amount which a widow who is not engaged in active
business receives from her property invested as trust funds.
Moreover, it is less and less true that the manager of the operations
of industry is necessarily the capitalist. To see this,
mark the executive managers (called </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">treasurers</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> by custom)
of cotton and woolen mills, who receive a remuneration entirely
distinct from any capital they may have invested in the
shares of the corporation; and the officials of the great mutual
insurance companies, who receive the wages of managers, but
for managing the capital of others. A large—by far the largest—part
of what is usually called profit, therefore, should be
treated as wages, and the forces which govern its amount are
the same as those affecting the amounts of all other kinds of
wages, such as are discussed in the preceding chapter. The
acknowledgment of this distinction is of extreme importance,
and affects, in a profound way, the whole question of distribution.
To include </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">wages of superintendence</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> in profits of
capital is to unnecessarily complicate one of the most serious
economic questions—namely, the relations of capital and labor.
</span>
<SPAN name="toc105" id="toc105"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 2. The Minimum of Profits; what produces Variations in the Amount of Profits.</span></h3>
<p>
The lowest rate of profit that can permanently exist
is that which is barely adequate, at the given place and time,
to afford an equivalent for the abstinence, risk, and exertion
implied in the employment of capital. From the gross profit
has first to be deducted as much as will form a fund sufficient
on the average to cover all losses incident to the employment.
Next, it must afford such an equivalent to the owner
of the capital for forbearing to consume it as is then and
there a sufficient motive to him to persist in his abstinence.
How much will be required to form this equivalent depends
on the comparative value placed, in the given society, upon
the present and the future (in the words formerly used): on
the strength of the effective desire of accumulation. Further,
after covering all losses, and remunerating the owner
for forbearing to consume, there must be something left to
recompense the labor and skill of the person who devotes
his time to the business.</p>
<p>
Such, then, is the minimum of profits: but that minimum
is exceedingly variable, and at some times and places
extremely low, on account of the great variableness of two
out of its three elements. That the rate of necessary remuneration
for abstinence, or in other words the effective desire
of accumulation, differs widely in different states of society
and civilization, has been seen in a former chapter. There
is a still wider difference in the element which consists in
compensation for risk.</p>
<p>
The remuneration of capital in different employments,
much more than the remuneration of labor, varies according
to the circumstances which render one employment more attractive
or more repulsive than another. The profits, for example,
of retail trade, in proportion to the capital employed,
exceed those of wholesale dealers or manufacturers, for this
reason among others, that there is less consideration attached
to the employment. The greatest, however, of these differences,
is that caused by difference of risk. The profits of a
gunpowder-manufacturer must be considerably greater than
the average, to make up for the peculiar risks to which he
and his property are constantly exposed. When, however,
as in the case of marine adventure, the peculiar risks are
capable of being, and commonly are, commuted for a fixed
payment, the premium of insurance takes its regular place
among the charges of production, and the compensation
which the owner of the ship or cargo receives for that payment
does not appear in the estimate of his profits, but is
included in the replacement of his capital.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
The minimum of profits can not properly include wages of
superintendence, nor is it so included, practically, in Mr. Mill's
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
discussions on the minimum of profits in a later part of this
volume. The operation of the various elements in changing the
amount of profits might be expressed as follows: As between
different countries and communities, who have a different effective
desire of accumulation, profits may vary with the element
of interest and risk; within the same district, where interest
is generally the same on the same security, profits may
vary with the risk attached to different industries; and, within
the same occupations, interest and risk being given, the wages
of superintendence may make a greater variation than either
of the other two causes—since a skillful manager may make a
large return, a poor one none at all. Or between two employments,
interest and risk remaining the same, wages of superintendence
sometimes produce a wide difference.
</span>
<p>
The portion, too, of the gross profit, which forms the
remuneration for the labor and skill of the dealer or producer,
is very different in different employments. This is
the explanation always given of the extraordinary rate of
apothecaries' profit. There are cases, again, in which a considerable
amount of labor and skill is required to conduct a
business necessarily of limited extent. In such cases a higher
than common rate of profit is necessary to yield only the
common rate of remuneration.</p>
<p>
All the natural monopolies (meaning thereby those which
are created by circumstances, and not by law) which produce
or aggravate the disparities in the remuneration of different
kinds of labor, operate similarly between different employments
of capital.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
In this passage Mr. Mill points out distinctly that the movement
up and down in the wages of a manager are governed by
the same laws as those which regulate differences in the different
rewards of labor, but yet he connects it improperly with
capital. It will be seen that Mr. Mill uses the term </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">gross
profit</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> on the next page in order to avoid the difficulty, which
rises unconsciously in his mind, of the anomalous presence of
the wages of the manager in the question of profit.
</span>
<SPAN name="toc106" id="toc106"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 3. General Tendency of Profits to an Equality.</span></h3>
<p>
After due allowance is made for these various causes
of inequality, namely, difference in the risk or agreeableness
of different employments, and natural or artificial monopolies
[which give greater or less wages of superintendence],
the rate of profit on capital in all employments tends
to an equality. That portion of profit which is properly
interest, and which forms the real remuneration for abstinence,
is strictly the same at the same time and place, whatever
be the employment. The rate of interest, on equally
good security, does not vary according to the destination of
the principal, though it does vary from time to time very
much, according to the circumstances of the market.</p>
<p>
It is far otherwise with gross profit, which, though (as
will presently be seen) it does not vary much from employment
to employment, varies very greatly from individual to
individual, and can scarcely be in any two cases the same.
It depends on the knowledge, talents, economy, and energy
of the capitalist himself, or of the agents whom he employs;
on the accidents of personal connection; and even on chance.
Hardly any two dealers in the same trade, even if their commodities
are equally good and equally cheap, carry on their
business at the same expense, or turn over their capital in
the same time. That equal capitals give equal profits, as a
general maxim of trade, would be as false as that equal age
or size gives equal bodily strength, or that equal reading or
experience gives equal knowledge. The effect depends as
much upon twenty other things as upon the single cause
specified. On an average (whatever may be the occasional
fluctuations) the various employments of capital are on such
a footing as to hold out, not equal profits, but equal expectations
of profit, to persons of average abilities and advantages.
By equal, I mean after making compensation for any
inferiority in the agreeableness or safety of an employment.
If the case were not so; if there were, evidently, and to
common experience, more favorable chances of pecuniary
success in one business than in others, more persons would
engage their capital in the business. If, on the contrary, a
business is not considered thriving; if the chances of profit
in it are thought to be inferior to those in other employments;
capital gradually leaves it, or at least new capital is
not attracted to it; and by this change in the distribution of
capital between the less profitable and the more profitable
employments, a sort of balance is restored.</p>
<p></p>
<ANTIMG src="images/capital-profitability.png" width-obs="259" height-obs="502" alt="Illustration: Parallel vertical lines AB and GD, with horizontal lines EG and FC joining them." />
<span style="font-size: 90%">
This may be easily shown by a diagram in
which the capital in one employment is represented
by </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">A B</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">, and which exceeds </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">C D</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">, that in
another employment, by the amount of </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">A F</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">. It
is not necessary that the whole of the excess,
</span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">A F</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> should be transferred to </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">C D</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> to make the
two capitals equal, but only </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">A E</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">, which, added
to </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">C D</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">, brings
</span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">C D</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> to an equality with </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">E B</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">.
</span>
<p>
This equalizing process, commonly described
as the transfer of capital from one employment
to another, is not necessarily the onerous, slow,
and almost impracticable operation which it is very often
represented to be. In the first place, it does not always
imply the actual removal of capital already embarked in an
employment. In a rapidly progressive state of capital, the
adjustment often takes place by means of the new accumulations
of each year, which direct themselves in preference
toward the more thriving trades. Even when a real transfer
of capital is necessary, it is by no means implied that any
of those who are engaged in the unprofitable employment
relinquish business and break up their establishments. The
numerous and multifarious channels of credit through which,
in commercial nations, unemployed capital diffuses itself over
the field of employment, flowing over in greater abundance
to the lower levels, are the means by which the equalization
is accomplished. The process consists in a limitation by one
class of dealers or producers and an extension by the other
of that portion of their business which is carried on with borrowed
capital.</p>
<span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Political economists say that capital sets toward the most
profitable trades, and that it rapidly leaves the less profitable
and non-paying trades. But in ordinary countries this is a slow
process, and some persons, who want to have ocular demonstrations
of abstract truths, have been inclined to doubt it because
they could not see it. The process would be visible
enough if you could only see the books of the bill-brokers and
the bankers. If the iron-trade ceases to be as profitable as
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
usual, less iron is sold; the fewer the sales the fewer the bills;
and in consequence the number of iron bills [at the banks] is
diminished. On the other hand, if, in consequence of a bad
harvest, the corn trade becomes on a sudden profitable, immediately
</span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">‘</span><span style="font-size: 90%">corn bills</span><span style="font-size: 90%">’</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> are created in large numbers, and, if good,
are discounted [at the banks]. Thus capital runs as surely
and instantly where it is most wanted, and where there is most
to be made of it, as water runs to find its level.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><SPAN id="noteref_177" name="noteref_177" href="#note_177"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">177</span></span></SPAN>
<p>
In the case of an altogether declining trade, in which it
is necessary that the production should be, not occasionally
varied, but greatly and permanently diminished, or perhaps
stopped altogether, the process of extricating the capital is,
no doubt, tardy and difficult, and almost always attended with
considerable loss; much of the capital fixed in machinery,
buildings, permanent works, etc., being either not applicable
to any other purpose, or only applicable after expensive alterations;
and time being seldom given for effecting the change
in the mode in which it would be effected with least loss,
namely, by not replacing the fixed capital as it wears out.
There is besides, in totally changing the destination of a capital,
so great a sacrifice of established connection, and of acquired
skill and experience, that people are always very slow
in resolving upon it, and hardly ever do so until long after
a change of fortune has become hopeless.</p>
<p>
In general, then, although profits are very different to
different individuals, and to the same individual in different
years, there can not be much diversity at the same time and
place in the average profits of different employments (other
than the standing differences necessary to compensate for difference
of attractiveness), except for short periods, or when
some great permanent revulsion has overtaken a particular
trade. It is true that, to persons with the same amount of
original means, there is more chance of making a large fortune
in some employments than in others. But it would be
found that in those same employments bankruptcies also are
more frequent, and that the chance of greater success is balanced
by a greater probability of complete failure.</p>
<SPAN name="toc107" id="toc107"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 4. The Cause of the Existence of any Profit; the Advances of Capitalists consist of Wages of Labor.</span></h3>
<p>
The preceding remarks have, I hope, sufficiently
elucidated what is meant by the common phrase, <span class="tei tei-q">“the ordinary
rate of profit,”</span> and the sense in which, and the limitations
under which, this ordinary rate has a real existence. It
now remains to consider what causes determine its amount.</p>
<p>
The cause of profit is, that labor produces more than is required
for its support; the reason why capital yields a profit
is, because food, clothing, materials, and tools last longer than
the time which is required to produce them; so that if a capitalist
supplies a party of laborers with these things, on condition
of receiving all they produce, they will, in addition to
reproducing their own necessaries and instruments, have a
portion of their time remaining, to work for the capitalist.
We thus see that profit arises, not from the incident of exchange,
but from the productive power of labor; and the
general profit of the country is always what the productive
power of labor makes it, whether any exchange takes place
or not. I proceed, in expansion of the considerations thus
briefly indicated, to exhibit more minutely the mode in which
the rate of profit is determined.</p>
<p>
I assume, throughout, the state of things which, where
the laborers and capitalists are separate classes, prevails, with
few exceptions, universally; namely, that the capitalist advances
the whole expenses, including the entire remuneration
of the laborer. That he should do so is not a matter of
inherent necessity; the laborer might wait until the production
is complete for all that part of his wages which exceeds
mere necessaries, and even for the whole, if he has funds in
hand sufficient for his temporary support. But in the latter
case the laborer is to that extent really a capitalist, investing
capital in the concern, by supplying a portion of the funds
necessary for carrying it on; and even in the former case
he may be looked upon in the same light, since, contributing
his labor at less than the market price, he may be regarded
as lending the difference to his employer, and receiving it
back with interest (on whatever principle computed) from
the proceeds of the enterprise.</p>
<p>
The capitalist, then, may be assumed to make all the
advances and receive all the produce. His profit consists of
the excess of the produce above the advances; his <em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-style: italic">rate</span></em> of
profit is the ratio which that excess bears to the amount
advanced.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
For example, if A advances 8,000 bushels of corn to laborers
in return for 10,000 yards of cloth (and if one bushel of
corn sells for the same sum as one yard of cloth), his profit
consists of 2,000 yards of cloth. The ratio of the excess, 2,000,
to 8,000, the outlay, or 25 per cent, is the </span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">rate</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%"> of profit. It is
not the ratio of 2,000 to 10,000.
</span>
<p>
But what do the advances consist of? It is, for the present,
necessary to suppose that the capitalist does not pay
any rent; has not to purchase the use of any appropriated
natural agent. The nature of rent, however, we have not
yet taken into consideration; and it will hereafter appear
that no practical error, on the question we are now examining,
is produced by disregarding it.</p>
<p>
If, then, leaving rent out of the question, we inquire in
what it is that the advances of the capitalist, for purposes of
production, consist, we shall find that they consist of wages
of labor.</p>
<p>
A large portion of the expenditure of every capitalist
consists in the direct payment of wages. What does not consist
of this is composed of materials and implements, including
buildings. But materials and implements are produced
by labor; and as our supposed capitalist is not meant to represent
a single employment, but to be a type of the productive
industry of the whole country, we may suppose that he
makes his own tools and raises his own materials. He does
this by means of previous advances, which, again, consist
wholly of wages. If we suppose him to buy the materials
and tools instead of producing them, the case is not altered:
he then repays to a previous producer the wages which that
previous producer has paid. It is true he repays it to him
with a profit; and, if he had produced the things himself, he
himself must have had that profit on this part of his outlay
as well as on every other part. The fact, however, remains,
that in the whole process of production, beginning with the
materials and tools and ending with the finished product, all
the advances have consisted of nothing but wages, except
that certain of the capitalists concerned have, for the sake of
general convenience, had their share of profit paid to them
before the operation was completed.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
This idea may be more clear, perhaps, if we imagine a large
corporation, not only making woolen cloth, but owning sheep-ranches,
where the raw materials are produced; the shops
where all machinery is made; and who even produce on their
own property all the food, clothing, shelter, and consumption
of the laborers employed by them. A line of division may be
passed through the returns in all these branches of the industry,
separating what is wages from what is profit. Then it can
be easily imagined that all the returns on one side, representing
profits, go to capitalists, no matter whether they are thousands
in number, or only one capitalist typifying the rest, or a
single corporation acting for many small capitalists.
</span>
<SPAN name="toc108" id="toc108"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="Book_II_Chapter_V_Section_5" id="Book_II_Chapter_V_Section_5" class="tei tei-anchor"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 5. The Rate of Profit depends on the Cost of Labor.</span></h3>
<p>
It thus appears that the two elements on which, and
which alone, the gains of the capitalists depend, are, first, the
magnitude of the produce, in other words, the productive
power of labor; and secondly, the proportion of that produce
obtained by the laborers themselves; the ratio which the remuneration
of the laborers bears to the amount they produce.</p>
<p>
We thus arrive at the conclusion of Ricardo and others,
that the rate of profits depends upon wages; rising as wages
fall, and falling as wages rise. In adopting, however, this
doctrine, I must insist upon making a most necessary alteration
in its wording. Instead of saying that profits depend
on wages, let us say (what Ricardo really meant) that they
depend on the <em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-style: italic">cost of labor</span></em>.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
This is an entirely different question from that concerning
the rate of wages before discussed (</span><SPAN href="#Book_II_Chapter_II" class="tei tei-ref"><span style="font-size: 90%">Book
II, Chap. II</span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%">). That
had to do with the amount of the capital which each laborer,
on an average, received as real wages, and this average rate
was affected by the number of competitors for labor, as compared
with the existing capital, taking into account the nature
of the industries in a country. An increase of population,
bringing more laborers to compete for employment, will lower
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
the average amount of real wages received by each one; and a
decrease of population will bring about the reverse. The rate of
wages, however, now that we are considering the matter from
the point of view of the capitalist, is but one of the things to
be considered affecting </span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">cost of labor</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%">. The former question was
one as to the distribution of capital; the latter is one as to the
amount by which the total production is greater than the total
capital advanced. Since all capital consists of advances to labor,
the present inquiry is one in regard to the quantity of advances
compared with the quantity returned; that is, the relation of
the total capital to the total production arising from the use of
that capital. In the diagram before used (</span><SPAN href="#Pg179" class="tei tei-ref"><span style="font-size: 90%"></span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%">) the question
is not how the contents of circle B are to be distributed, but the
relative size of circle B to circle A. In order to produce circle
A, it is necessary to advance what is represented by circle B.
</span>
<p>
Wages and the cost of labor; what labor brings in to
the laborer and what it costs to the capitalist are ideas
quite distinct, and which it is of the utmost importance to
keep so. For this purpose it is essential not to designate
them, as is almost always done, by the same name. Wages,
in public discussions, both oral and printed, being looked
upon from the same point of view of the payers, much
oftener than from that of the receivers, nothing is more common
than to say that wages are high or low, meaning only
that the cost of labor [to the capitalist] is high or low. The
reverse of this would be oftener the truth: the cost of labor
is frequently at its highest where wages are lowest. This
may arise from two causes. (1.) In the first place, the labor,
though cheap, may be inefficient.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
The facts presented by Mr. Brassey</span><SPAN id="noteref_178" name="noteref_178" href="#note_178"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">178</span></span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%"> very fully illustrate
this principle. Although French workmen in their ship-yards
receive less wages for the same kind of work than the English
workmen in English yards, yet it costs less per ton to build
ships in England than in France. The same correspondence
between high wages and efficient work was found to be true of
railway construction in different parts of the world. With
different character, varying amounts of industrial energy, varying
intelligence, and endurance, different people do not have
the same efficiency of labor. It is ascertained that inefficiency
is, as a rule, accompanied by low wages. Even though wages
paid for ordinary labor in constructing railways were in India
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
only from nine to twelve cents a day, and in England from
seventy-five to eighty-seven cents a day, yet it cost as much to
build a mile of railway in India as in England. The English
laborer gave a full equivalent for his higher wages. Moreover,
while an English weaver tends from two to three times as
many looms as his Russian competitor, the workman in the
United States, it is said, will tend even more than the Englishman.
In American sailing-vessels, also, a less number of sailors,
relatively to the tonnage, is required than in English sailing-ships.
Mr. Brassey, besides, came to the conclusion that the
working power, or efficiency, of ordinary English laborers was
to the French as five to three.
</span>
<p>
(2.) The other cause which renders wages and the cost of
labor no real criteria of one another is the varying costliness
of the articles which the laborer consumes. If these are
cheap, wages, in the sense which is of importance to the
laborer, may be high, and yet the cost of labor may be low;
if dear, the laborer may be wretchedly off, though his labor
may cost much to the capitalist. This last is the condition
of a country over-peopled in relation to its land; in which,
food being dear, the poorness of the laborer's real reward
does not prevent labor from costing much to the purchaser,
and low wages and low profits coexist. The opposite case
is exemplified in the United States of America. The laborer
there enjoys a greater abundance of comforts than in any
other country of the world, except some of the newest colonies;
but owing to the cheap price at which these comforts
can be obtained (combined with the great efficiency of the
labor), the cost of labor to the capitalist is considerably lower
than in Europe. It must be so, since the rate of profit is
higher; as indicated by the rate of interest, which is six per
cent at New York when it is three or three and a quarter
per cent in London.</p>
<p>
The cost of labor, then, is, in the language of mathematics,
a function of three variables: (1) the efficiency of labor;
(2) the wages of labor (meaning thereby the real reward [or
real wages] of the laborer); and (3) the greater or less cost<SPAN id="noteref_179" name="noteref_179" href="#note_179"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">179</span></span></SPAN>
at which the articles composing that real reward can be produced
or purchased. It is plain that the cost of labor to the
capitalist must be influenced by each of these three circumstances,
and by no others. These, therefore, are also the circumstances
which determine the rate of profit; and it can not
be in any way affected except through one or other of them.</p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
The efficiency of labor, in this connection, is highly important
in its practical aspects, and as affecting the labor question,
because as a function of cost of labor, that is, as an element
affecting the quantity of things advanced to the laborers
in comparison with the quantity of things returned to the employer,
it includes the whole influence of machinery, labor-saving
devices, and the results of invention. The quantity of
produce depends, for a given advance, on the kind of machinery,
the speed with which it is run, and on the general state of
the arts and industrial inventions. The extent to which the
productive capacity of a single laborer has been increased in
the United States has been almost incredible. Instead of
weaving cloth by hand, as was done a hundred years ago,
</span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">one operative in Lowell, working one year, can produce the
cotton fabric needed for the year's supply of 1,500 to 1,800
Chinese.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> Moreover, there is no question as to the fact that
no nation in the world compares with ours in the power to invent,
construct, and manage the most ingenious and complicated
machinery. The inventive faculty belongs to every class
in our country; and, in studying cost of labor, it must be well
borne in mind that the efficiency of American labor, particularly
as combined with mechanical appliances, is one of the
great causes of our enormous production. The result of this,
for instance, has been that, without lowering profits, although
the price of cloth has been greatly reduced, employers have
been able to raise the wages of operatives, and shorten their
hours of labor, because machinery has so vastly increased the
production for a given outlay. As one of a few facts showing
this tendency in the last fifty years, note the following table,
taken from the books of the Namquit cotton-mill in Bristol,
Rhode Island:
</span></p>
<table summary="This is a table" cellspacing="0" class="tei tei-table" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><colgroup span="3"></colgroup><tbody><tr class="tei tei-row"><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">Kind Of Labor.</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">1841.</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">1884.</span></td></tr><tr class="tei tei-row"><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">Card-room help, per week</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">$3.28</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">$5.40</span></td></tr><tr class="tei tei-row"><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">Card-strippers, per week</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">4.98</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">6.00</span></td></tr><tr class="tei tei-row"><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">Weavers, per week</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">4.75</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">6.00</span></td></tr><tr class="tei tei-row"><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">Carding-room overseer, per week</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">7.00</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">13.50</span></td></tr></tbody></table>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
The hours per week
have decreased in the
same time from 84 to 66,
while the product of the
mill in pounds has increased
25 per cent. It
may be unnecessary, perhaps,
to say that these figures represent the current wages in
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
other mills at the same periods; and that these facts can be
sustained by the records of other mills.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
In its economic effect we must also consider, under efficiency,
the whole question of natural advantages of soil, climate,
and natural resources. Laborers of the same skill, paid
the same real wages, of the same cost, will produce a vastly
greater amount of wheat in Dakota than in Vermont or England.
This is the chief reason why profits are so high in the
United States. In many industries we have very marked natural
advantages, which permits a high reward to labor, and yet
yields a high profit to the capitalist. This applies not merely
to agriculture, but to all the extractive industries, such as the
production of petroleum, wood, copper, etc.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
In short, the whole matter of ease and difficulty of production,
of high or low cost of production, taking it in the sense
of great or little sacrifice (compare carefully
</span><SPAN href="#Book_III_Chapter_II_Section_4" class="tei tei-ref"><span style="font-size: 90%">Book III, Chap.
II, § 4</span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%">), comes in under the element of efficiency, in cost of
labor. The reader can not be too strongly urged to connect
different parts of the economic system together. And the
questions of Cost of Labor and Cost of Production are of
paramount importance to a proper understanding of political
economy.
</span></p>
<p>
If labor generally became more efficient, without being
more highly rewarded; if, without its becoming less efficient,
its remuneration fell, no increase taking place in the
cost of the articles composing that remuneration; or if those
articles became less costly, without the laborers obtaining
more of them; in any one of these three cases, profits would
rise. If, on the contrary, labor became less efficient (as it
might do from diminished bodily vigor in the people, destruction
of fixed capital, or deteriorated education); or if
the laborer obtained a higher remuneration, without any increased
cheapness in the things composing it; or if, without
his obtaining more, that which he did obtain became more
costly; profits, in all these cases, would suffer a diminution.
And there is no other combination of circumstances in which
the general rate of profit of a country, in all employments
indifferently, can either fall or rise.</p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
The connection of profit with the three constituents of cost
of labor may probably be better seen by aid of the following
illustration; it being premised that as yet money is not used,
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
and that the laborers are paid in the articles which their
money wages would have bought had money been used. For
simplicity we will suppose that all articles of the laborer's consumption
are represented by corn. Imagine a large woolen-mill
employing 500 men, and paying them in corn; and suppose
that one yard of woolen cloth exchanges for one bushel of corn
in the open market. In the beginning, with a given condition
of efficiency, suppose that each man produces on an average
1,200 yards of cloth, for which he is paid 1,000 bushels of corn:
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
500 men, each producing 1,200 yards, give a total product of 600,000 yards.</span><br/><span style="font-size: 90%">
500 men, each paid 1,000 bushels, cause an outlay of 500,000 yards.</span><br/><span style="font-size: 90%">
Profit: 100,000 yards.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
(1.) Now suppose a change increasing the efficiency of labor
to such an extent that each laborer produces 1,300 instead
of 1,200 yards, then the account will stand, if the other elements
remain unchanged:
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
500 men, each producing 1,300 yards, give a total product of 650,000 yards.</span><br/><span style="font-size: 90%">
500 men, each paid 1,000 bushels, cause an outlay of 500,000 yards.</span><br/><span style="font-size: 90%">
Profit: 150,000 yards.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
(2.) If efficiency and the cost of producing food remain
the same as at first, suppose a change to occur which raises
the quantity of corn each laborer receives from 1,000 to 1,100,
or, as it is called, increases his real wages—then the account
will be:
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
500 men, each producing 1,200 yards, give a total product of 600,000 yards.</span><br/><span style="font-size: 90%">
500 men, each paid 1,100 bushels, cause an outlay of 550,000 yards.</span><br/><span style="font-size: 90%">
Profit: 50,000 yards.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
(3.) If efficiency and real wages remain the same, suppose
such an increase in the cost to the employers of obtaining
corn that they are obliged to give one and one tenth yard of
their goods for one bushel of corn (1,000 bushels of corn costing
them 1,100 yards of cloth), then the statement will read:
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
500 men, each producing 1,200 yards, give a total product of 600,000 yards.</span><br/><span style="font-size: 90%">
500 men, each paid 1,000 bushels, cause an outlay of 550,000 yards.</span><br/><span style="font-size: 90%">
Profit: 50,000 yards.
</span></p>
<hr class="page" />
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />