<SPAN name="toc157" id="toc157"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="pdf158" id="pdf158"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="Book_III_Chapter_VII" id="Book_III_Chapter_VII" class="tei tei-anchor"></SPAN>
<h2><span>Chapter VII. Of A Double Standard And Subsidiary Coins.</span></h2>
<SPAN name="toc159" id="toc159"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 1. Objections to a Double Standard.</span></h3>
<p>
Though the qualities necessary to fit any commodity
for being used as money are rarely united in any considerable
perfection, there are two commodities which possess
them in an eminent and nearly an equal degree—the two
precious metals, as they are called—gold and silver. Some
nations have accordingly attempted to compose their circulating
medium of these two metals indiscriminately.</p>
<p>
There is an obvious convenience in making use of the
more costly metal for larger payments, and the cheaper one
for smaller; and the only question relates to the mode in
which this can best be done. The mode most frequently
adopted has been to establish between the two metals a fixed
proportion [to decide by law, for example, that sixteen
grains of silver should be equivalent to one grain of gold];
and it being left free to every one who has a [dollar] to pay,
either to pay it in the one metal or in the other.</p>
<p>
If [their] natural or cost values always continued to bear
the same ratio to one another, the arrangement would be unobjectionable.
This, however, is far from being the fact.
Gold and silver, though the least variable in value of all
commodities, are not invariable, and do not always vary
simultaneously. Silver, for example, was lowered in permanent
value more than gold by the discovery of the American
mines; and those small variations of value which take place
occasionally do not affect both metals alike. Suppose such
a variation to take place—the value of the two metals relatively
to one another no longer agreeing with their rated
proportion—one or other of them will now be rated below its
bullion value, and there will be a profit to be made by melting
it.</p>
<p>
Suppose, for example, that gold rises in value relatively
to silver, so that the quantity of gold in a sovereign is now
worth more than the quantity of silver in twenty shillings.
Two consequences will ensue. No debtor will any longer
find it his interest to pay in gold. He will always pay in
silver, because twenty shillings are a legal tender for a debt
of one pound, and he can procure silver convertible into
twenty shillings for less gold than that contained in a sovereign.
The other consequence will be that, unless a sovereign
can be sold for more than twenty shillings, all the
sovereigns will be melted, since as bullion they will purchase
a greater number of shillings than they exchange for as coin.
The converse of all this would happen if silver, instead of
gold, were the metal which had risen in comparative value.
A sovereign would not now be worth so much as twenty
shillings, and whoever had a pound to pay would prefer paying
it by a sovereign; while the silver coins would be collected
for the purpose of being melted, and sold as bullion
for gold at their real value—that is, above the legal valuation.
The money of the community, therefore, would never
really consist of both metals, but of the one only which, at
the particular time, best suited the interest of debtors; and
the standard of the currency would be constantly liable to
change from the one metal to the other, at a loss, on each
change, of the expense of coinage on the metal which fell
out of use.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
This is the operation by which is carried into effect the law
of Sir Thomas Gresham (a merchant of the time of Elizabeth)
to the purport that </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">money of less value drives out money of
more value,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> where both are legal payments among individuals.
A celebrated instance is that where the clipped coins of England
were received by the state on equal terms with new and
perfect coin before 1695. They hanged men and women, but
they did not prevent the operation of Gresham's law and the
disappearance of the perfect coins. When the state refused the
clipped coins at legal value, by no longer receiving them in payment
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
of taxes, the trouble ceased.</span><SPAN id="noteref_234" name="noteref_234" href="#note_234"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">234</span></span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%"> Jevons gives a striking
illustration of the same law: </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">At the time of the treaty of
1858 between Great Britain, the United States, and Japan,
which partially opened up the last country to European traders,
a very curious system of currency existed in Japan. The most
valuable Japanese coin was the kobang, consisting of a thin
oval disk of gold about two inches long, and one and a quarter
inch wide, weighing two hundred grains, and ornamented in a
very primitive manner. It was passing current in the towns of
Japan for four silver itzebus, but was worth in English money
about 18</span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">s.</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> 5</span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">d.</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">,
whereas the silver itzebu was equal only to
about 1</span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">s.</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> 4</span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">d.</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">
[four itzebus being worth in English money 5</span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">s.</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">
4</span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">d.</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">]. The earliest European traders enjoyed a rare opportunity
for making profit. By buying up the kobangs at the native
rating they trebled their money, until the natives, perceiving
what was being done, withdrew from circulation the remainder
of the gold.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><SPAN id="noteref_235" name="noteref_235" href="#note_235"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">235</span></span></SPAN>
<p>
It appears, therefore, that the value of money is liable to
more frequent fluctuations when both metals are a legal tender
at a fixed valuation than when the exclusive standard of
the currency is either gold or silver. Instead of being only
affected by variations in the cost of production of one metal,
it is subject to derangement from those of two. The particular
kind of variation to which a currency is rendered
more liable by having two legal standards is a fall of value,
or what is commonly called a depreciation, since practically
that one of the two metals will always be the standard of
which the real has fallen below the rated value. If the tendency
of the metals be to rise in value, all payments will be
made in the one which has risen least; and, if to fall, then
in that which has fallen most.</p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
While liable to </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">more frequent fluctuations,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> prices do not
follow the </span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">extreme</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%"> fluctuations of both metals, as some suppose,
and as is shown by the following diagram.</span><SPAN id="noteref_236" name="noteref_236" href="#note_236"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">236</span></span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%"> A represents the
line of the value of gold, and B of silver, relatively to some
third commodity represented by the horizontal line. Superposing
these curves, C would show the line of </span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">extreme</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%"> variations,
while since prices would follow the metal which </span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">falls</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%"> in
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
value, D would show the actual course of variations. While
the fluctuations are more frequent in D, they are less extreme
than in C.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="text-align: center; margin-bottom: 0.90em"></p>
<ANTIMG src="images/double-standard.png" width-obs="700" height-obs="465" alt="Illustration." title="Chart showing the line of prices under a double standard." /><span style="font-size: 90%">Chart showing the line of prices under a double standard.</span>
<SPAN name="toc160" id="toc160"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="Book_III_Chapter_VII_Section_2" id="Book_III_Chapter_VII_Section_2" class="tei tei-anchor"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 2. The use of the two metals as money, and the management of Subsidiary Coins.</span></h3>
<p>
The plan of a double standard is still occasionally
brought forward by here and there a writer or orator as a
great improvement in currency.</p>
<p>
It is probable that, with most of its adherents, its chief
merit is its tendency to a sort of depreciation, there being at
all times abundance of supporters for any mode, either open
or covert, of lowering the standard. [But] the advantage
without the disadvantages of a double standard seems to be
best obtained by those nations with whom one only of the
two metals is a legal tender, but the other also is coined, and
allowed to pass for whatever value the market assigns to it.</p>
<p>
When this plan is adopted, it is naturally the more costly
metal which is left to be bought and sold as an article of
commerce. But nations which, like England, adopt the
more costly of the two as their standard, resort to a different
expedient for retaining them both in circulation, namely (1),
to make silver a legal tender, but only for small payments.
In England no one can be compelled to receive silver in payment
for a larger amount than forty shillings. With this
regulation there is necessarily combined another, namely (2),
that silver coin should be rated, in comparison with gold,
somewhat above its intrinsic value; that there should not
be, in twenty shillings, as much silver as is worth a sovereign;
for, if there were, a very slight turn of the market
in its favor would make it worth more than a sovereign, and
it would be profitable to melt the silver coin. The overvaluation
of the silver coin creates an inducement to buy
silver and send it to the mint to be coined, since it is given
back at a higher value than properly belongs to it; this,
however, has been guarded against (3) by limiting the quantity
of the silver coinage, which is not left, like that of gold,
to the discretion of individuals, but is determined by the
Government, and restricted to the amount supposed to be required
for small payments. The only precaution necessary
is, not to put so high a valuation upon the silver as to hold
out a strong temptation to private coining.</p>
<SPAN name="toc161" id="toc161"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="Book_III_Chapter_VII_Section_3" id="Book_III_Chapter_VII_Section_3" class="tei tei-anchor"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 3. The experience of the United States with a double standard from 1792 to 1883.</span></h3>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
The experience of the United States with a double
standard, extending as it does from 1792 to 1873 without a
break, and from 1878 to the present time, is a most valuable
source of instruction in regard to the practical working of bimetallism.
While we have nominally had a double standard,
in reality we have either had one alone, or been in a transition
from one to the other standard; and the history of our coinage
strikingly illustrates the truth that the natural values of the
two metals, in spite of all legislation, so vary relatively to each
other that a constant ratio can not be maintained for any
length of time; and that </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">the poor money drives out the
good,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> according to Gresham's statement. For clearness, the
period may be divided, in accordance with the changes of legislation,
into four divisions:
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
I. 1792-1834. Transition from gold to silver.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
II. 1834-1853. Transition from silver to gold.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
III. 1853-1878. Single gold currency (except 1862-1879,
the paper period).
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
IV. 1878-1884. Transition from gold to silver.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
I. With the establishment of the mint, Hamilton agreed
upon the use of both gold and silver in our money, at a ratio
of 15 to 1: that is, that the amount of pure silver in a dollar
should be fifteen times the weight of gold in a dollar. So,
while the various Spanish dollars then in circulation in the
United States seemed to contain on the average about 371-¼
grains of pure silver, and since Hamilton believed the relative
market value of gold and silver to be about 1 to 15, he
put 1/15 of 371-¼ grains, or 24-¾ grains of pure gold, into the
gold dollar. It was the best possible example of the bimetallic
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
system to be found, and the mint ratio was intended to conform
to the market ratio. If this conformity could have been maintained,
there would have been no disturbance. But a cause was
already in operation affecting the supply of one of the metals—silver—wholly
independent of legislation, and without correspondingly
affecting gold.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
Two periods of production of silver, in which the production
of silver was great relatively to gold, stand out prominently
in the history of that metal. (1) One was the enormous
yield from the mines of the New World, continuing from 1545
to about 1640, and (2) the only other period of great production
at all comparable with it (that is, as regards the production
of silver relatively to gold) was that lasting from 1780 to
1820, due to the richness of the Mexican silver-mines. The
first period of ninety-five years was longer than the second,
which was only forty years; yet while about forty-seven times
as much silver as gold was produced on an average during the
first period, the average annual amount of silver produced
relatively to gold was probably a little greater from 1780 to
1820. The effect of the first period in lowering the relation
of silver to gold is well recognized in the history of the precious
metals (see </span><SPAN href="#Chart_X" class="tei tei-ref"><span style="font-size: 90%">Chart X</span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%"> for the fall in the value of silver
relatively to gold); that the effect of the second period on the
value of silver has not been greater than was actually caused—it
has not been small—is explicable only by the laws of the
value of money. If you let the same amount of water into a
small reservoir which you let into a large one, the level of the
former will be raised more than the level of the latter. The
great production of the first period was added to a very small
existing stock of silver; that of the second period was added
to a stock increased by the great previous production just mentioned.
The smallness of the annual product relatively to the
total quantity existing in the world requires some time, even
for a production of silver forty-seven times greater than the
gold production, to take its effect on the value of the total
silver stock in existence. The effect of this process was beginning
to be felt soon after the United States decided on a double
standard. For this reason the value of silver was declining about
1800, and, although the annual silver product fell off seriously
after 1820, the value of silver continued to decline even after
that time, because the increased production, dating back to
1780, was just beginning to make itself felt. Thus we have
the phenomenon—which seems very difficult for some persons
to understand—of a falling off in the annual production of silver,
accompanied by a decrease in its value relatively to gold.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
This diminishing value of silver began to affect the coinage
of the United States as early as 1811, and by 1820 the
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
disappearance of gold was everywhere commented upon. The
process by which this result is produced is a simple one, and
is adopted as soon as a margin of profit is seen arising from a
divergence between the mint and market ratios. In 1820 the
market ratio of gold to silver was 1 to 15.7—that is, the amount
of gold in a dollar (24-¾ grains) would exchange for 15.7 times
as many grains of silver in the market, in the form of bullion;
while at the mint, in the form of coin, it would exchange for
only 15 times as many grains of silver. A broker having 1,000
gold dollars could buy with them in the market silver bullion
enough (1,000 × 15.7 grains) to have coined, when presented
at the mint, 1,000 dollars in silver pieces, and yet have left
over as a profit by the operation 700 grains of silver. So long
as this can be done, silver (the cheapest money) will be presented
at the mint, and gold (the dearest money) will become
an article of merchandise too valuable to be used as money
when the cheaper silver is legally as good. The best money,
therefore, disappears from circulation, as it did in the United
States before 1820, owing to the fall in the value of silver. It
is to be said, that it has been seriously urged by some writers
that silver did not fall, but that gold rose, in value, owing to
the demand of England for resumption in 1819.</span><SPAN id="noteref_237" name="noteref_237" href="#note_237"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">237</span></span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%"> Chronology
kills this view; for the change in the value of silver began too
early to have been due to English measures, even if conclusive
reasons have not been given above why silver should naturally
have fallen in value.
</span></p>
<SPAN name="Chart_X" id="Chart_X" class="tei tei-anchor"></SPAN>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="text-align: center; margin-bottom: 0.90em"></p>
<ANTIMG src="images/chartx.png" width-obs="700" height-obs="379" alt="Illustration." title="Chart X. Chart showing the Changes in the Relative Values of Gold and Silver from 1501 to 1880. From 1501 to 1680 a space is allotted to each 20 years; from 1681 to 1871, to each 10 years; from 1876 to 1880, to each year." /><span style="font-size: 90%">Chart X. Chart showing the Changes in the Relative Values of
Gold and Silver from 1501 to 1880. From 1501 to 1680 a space is allotted to each
20 years; from 1681 to 1871, to each 10 years; from 1876 to 1880, to each year.</span>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
II. The change in the relative values of gold and silver finally
forced the United States to change their mint ratio in 1834.
Two courses were open to us: (1) either to increase the quantity
of silver in the dollar until the dollar of silver was intrinsically
worth the gold in the gold dollar; or (2) debase the
gold dollar-piece until it was reduced in value proportionate to
the depreciation of silver since 1792. The latter expedient,
without any seeming regard to the effect on contracts and the
integrity of our monetary standard, was adopted: 6.589 per
cent was taken out of the gold dollar, leaving it containing
23.22 grains of pure gold; and as the silver dollar remained
unchanged (371-¼ grains) the mint ratio established was 1 to
15.988, or, as commonly stated, 1 to 16. Did this correspond
with the market ratio then existing? No. Having seen the
former steady fall in silver, and believing that it would continue,
Congress hoped to anticipate any further fall by making
the mint ratio of gold to silver a little larger than the market
ratio. This was done by establishing the mint ratio of 1 to
15.988, while the market ratio in 1834 was 1 to 15.73. Here,
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
again, appeared the difficulty arising from the attempt to balance
a ratio on a movable fulcrum. It will be seen that the
act of 1834 set at work forces for another change in the coinage—forces
of a similar kind, but working in exactly the opposite
direction to those previous to 1834. A dollar of gold coin
would now exchange for more grains of silver at the mint
(15.98) than it would in the form of bullion in the market
(15.73). Therefore it would be more profitable to put gold into
coin than exchange it as bullion. Gold was sent to the mint,
while silver began to be withdrawn from circulation, silver
now being more valuable as bullion than as coin. By 1840 a
silver dollar was worth 102 cents in gold.</span><SPAN id="noteref_238" name="noteref_238" href="#note_238"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">238</span></span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%"> This movement,
which was displacing silver with gold, received a surprising
and unexpected impetus by the gold discoveries of California
and Australia in 1849, before mentioned, and made gold less
valuable relatively to silver, by lowering the value of gold.
Here, again, was another natural cause, independent of legislation,
and not to be foreseen, altering the value of one of the
precious metals, and in exactly the opposite direction from that
in the previous period, when silver was lowered by the increase
from the Mexican mines. In 1853 a silver dollar was worth
104 cents in gold (i.e., of a gold dollar containing 23.22 grains);
but, some years before, all silver dollars had disappeared from
use, and only gold was in circulation. For a large part of this
period we had in reality a single standard of gold, the other
metal not being able to stay in the currency.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
III. After our previous experience, the impossibility of retaining
both metals in the coinage together, on equal terms,
now came to be generally recognized, and was accepted by
Congress in the legislation of 1853. This act made no further
changes intended to adapt the mint to the market ratios, but
remained satisfied with the gold circulation. But hitherto no
regard had been paid to the principles on which a subsidiary
coinage is based, as explained by Mr. Mill in the last section
(</span><SPAN href="#Book_III_Chapter_VII_Section_2" class="tei tei-ref"><span style="font-size: 90%">§ 2</span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%">).
The act of 1853, while acquiescing in the single gold
standard, had for its purpose the readjustment of the subsidiary
coins, which, together with silver dollar-pieces, had all
gone out of circulation. Before this, two halves, four quarters,
or ten dimes contained the same quantity of pure silver as
the dollar-piece (371-¼ grains); therefore, when it became profitable
to withdraw the dollar-pieces and substitute gold, it gave
exactly the same profit to withdraw two halves or four quarters
in silver. For this reason all the subsidiary silver had
gone out of circulation, and there was no </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">small change</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> in
the country. The legislation of 1853 rectified this error: (1)
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
by reducing the quantity of pure silver in a dollar's worth of
subsidiary coin to 345.6 grains. By making so much less an
amount of silver equal to a dollar of small coins, it was more
valuable in that shape than as bullion, and there was no reason
for melting it, or withdrawing it (since even if gold and silver
changed considerably in their relative values, 345.6 grains of
silver could not easily rise sufficiently to become equal in
value to a gold dollar, when 371-¼ grains were worth only 104
cents of the gold dollar); (2) this over-valuation of silver in
subsidiary coin would cause a great flow of silver to the mint,
since silver would be more valuable in subsidiary coin than as
bullion; but this was prevented by the provision (section 4 of
the act of 1853) that the amount or the small coinage should be
limited according to the discretion of the Secretary of the
Treasury; and, (3) in order that the overvalued small coinage
might not be used for purposes other than for effecting change,
its legal-tender power was restricted to payments not exceeding
five dollars. This system, a single gold standard for large,
and silver for small, payments, continued without question, and
with great convenience, until the days of the war, when paper
money (1862-1879) drove out (by its cheapness, again) both
gold and silver. Paper was far cheaper than the cheapest of
the two metals.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="text-align: center; margin-bottom: 0.90em"></p>
<ANTIMG src="images/relative-gold-silver.png" width-obs="700" height-obs="608" alt="Illustration." title="Relative values of gold and silver, by months, in 1876." /><span style="font-size: 90%">Relative values of gold and silver, by months, in 1876.</span>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
The mere fact that the silver dollar-piece had not circulated
since even long before 1853 led the authorities to drop
out the provisions for the coinage of silver dollars and in 1873
remove it from the list of legal coins (at the ratio of 1 to 15.98,
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
the obsolete ratio fixed as far back as 1834). This is what
is known as the </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">demonetization</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> of silver. It had no effect
on the circulation of silver dollars, since none were in use, and
had not been for more than twenty-five years. There had been
no desire up to this time to use silver, since it was more expensive
than gold; indeed, it is somewhat humiliating to our sense
of national honor to reflect that it was not until silver fell so
surprisingly in value (in 1876) that the agitation for its use in
the coinage arose. When a silver dollar was worth 104 cents,
no one wanted it as a means of liquidating debts; when it
came to be worth 86 cents, it was capable of serving debtors
even better than the then appreciating greenbacks. Thus, while
from 1853 (and even before) we had legally two standards,
of both gold and silver, but really only one, that of gold, from
1873 to 1878 we had both legally and really only one standard,
that of gold.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
It might be here added, that I have spoken of the silver
dollar as containing 371-¼ grains of pure silver. Of course,
alloy is mixed with the pure silver, sufficient, in 1792, to
make the original dollar weigh 416 grains in all, its </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">standard</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">
weight. In 1837 the amount of alloy was changed from
1/12 to 1/10 of the standard weight, which (as the 371-¼ grains of
pure silver were unchanged) gave the total weight of the dollar
as 412-½ grains, whence the familiar name assigned to this piece.
In 1873, moreover, the mint was permitted to put its stamp and
devices—to what was not money at all, but a </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">coined ingot</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">—on
378 grains of pure silver (420 grains, standard), known as
the </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">trade-dollar.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> It was intended by this means to make
United States silver more serviceable in the Asiatic trade.
Oriental nations care almost exclusively for silver in payments.
The Mexican silver dollar contained 377-¼ grains of pure silver;
the Japanese yen, 374-4/10; and the United States dollar, 371-¼.
By making the </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">trade-dollar</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> slightly heavier than any coin
used in the Eastern world, it would give our silver a new market;
and the United States Government was simply asked to
certify to the fineness and weight by coining it, provided the
owners of silver paid the expenses of coinage. Inadvertently
the trade-dollar was included in the list of coins in the act of
1873 which were legal tender for payments of five dollars, but,
when this was discovered, it was repealed in 1876. So that the
trade-dollar was not a legal coin, in any sense (although it contained
more silver than the 412-½-grains dollar). They ceased
to be coined in 1878, to which time there had been made $35,959,360.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
IV. In February, 1878, an indiscreet and unreasonable movement
induced Congress to authorize the recoinage of the silver
dollar-piece at the obsolete ratio of 1834 (1 to 15.98), while the
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
market ratio was 1 to 17.87. So extraordinary a reversal of all
sound principles and such blindness to our previous experience
could be explained only by a desire to force this country to
use a silver coinage only, and had its origin with the owners
of silver-mines, aided by the desires of debtors for a cheap
unit in which to absolve themselves from their indebtedness.
There was no pretense of setting up a double standard about
it; for it was evident to the most ignorant that so great a disproportion
between the mint and market ratios must inevitably
lead to the disappearance of gold entirely. This would happen,
if owners could bring their silver freely, in any amounts, to
the mint for coinage (</span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Free Coinage</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">), and so exchange silver
against gold coin for the purpose of withdrawing gold, since
gold would exchange for less as coin than as bullion. This
immediate result was prevented by a provision in the law,
which prevented the </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">free coinage</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> of silver, and required the
Government itself to buy silver and coin at least $2,000,000 in
silver each month. This retarded, but will not ultimately prevent,
the change from the present gold to a single silver standard.
At the rate of $24,000,000 a year, it is only a question
of time when the Treasury will be obliged to pay out, for
its regular disbursements on the public debt, silver in such
amounts as will drive gold out of circulation. In February,
1884, it was feared that this was already at hand, and was
practically reached in the August following. Unless a repeal
of the law is reached very soon, the uncomfortable spectacle
will be seen of a gradual disarrangement of prices, and consequently
of trade, arising from a change of the standard.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
In order that the alternate movements of silver and gold to
the mint for coinage may be seen, there is appended a statement
of the coinage</span><SPAN id="noteref_239" name="noteref_239" href="#note_239"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">239</span></span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%"> during the above periods, which well
shows the effects of Gresham's law.
</span></p>
<table summary="This is a table" cellspacing="0" class="tei tei-table" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><colgroup span="4"></colgroup><tbody><tr class="tei tei-row"><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">Ratio in the mint and in the market.</span></td>
<td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">Period.</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">Gold coinage.</span></td>
<td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">Silver dollars coined.</span></td></tr><tr class="tei tei-row"><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">1:15 (silver lower in market)</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">1792-1834</span></td>
<td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">$11,825,890</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">$36,275,077</span></td></tr><tr class="tei tei-row"><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">1:15.98 (gold lower in market)</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">1834-1853</span></td>
<td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">224,965,730</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">42,936,294</span></td></tr><tr class="tei tei-row"><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">1:15.98 (gold lower in market)</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">1853-1873</span></td>
<td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">544,864,921</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">5,538,948</span></td></tr><tr class="tei tei-row"><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">Single gold standard.</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">1873-1878</span></td>
<td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">166,253,816</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">........</span></td></tr><tr class="tei tei-row"><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">1:15.98 (silver lower, but no free coinage)</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">1878-1883</span></td>
<td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">354,019,865</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">147,255,899</span></td></tr></tbody></table>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
From this it will be seen that there has been an enforced
coinage by the Treasury, of almost twice as many silver dollars
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
since 1878 as were coined in all the history of the mint
before, since the establishment of the Government.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
It may, perhaps, be asked why the silver dollar of 412-½
grains, being worth intrinsically only from 86 to 89 cents, does
not depreciate to that value. The Government buys the silver,
owns the coin, and holds all that it can not induce the public
to receive voluntarily; so that but a part of the total coinage
is out of the Treasury. And most of the coins issued are returned
for deposit and silver certificates received in return.
There being no free coinage, and no greater amount in circulation
than satisfies the demand for change, instead of small
bills, the dollar-pieces will circulate at their full value, on the
principle of subsidiary coin, even though overvalued. And the
silver certificates practically go through a process of constant
redemption by being received for customs dues equally with
gold. When they become too great in quantity to be needed
for such purposes, then we may look for the depreciation with
good reason.</span><SPAN id="noteref_240" name="noteref_240" href="#note_240"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">240</span></span></SPAN></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
There are, then, the following kinds of legal tender in the
United States in 1884: (1) Gold coins (if not below tolerance);
(2) the silver dollar of 412-½ grains; (3) United States notes
(except for customs and interest on the public debt); (4) subsidiary
silver coinage, to the amount of five dollars; and (5)
minor coins, to the amount of twenty-five cents.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
The question of a double standard has provoked no little
vehement discussion and has called forth a considerable literature
since the fall of silver in 1876. A body of opinion exists,
best represented in this country by F. A. Walker and S. D.
Horton, that the relative values of gold and silver may be kept
unchanged, in spite of all natural causes, by the force of law,
which, provided that enough countries join in the plan, shall
fix the ratio of exchange in the coinage for all great commercial
countries, and by this means keep the coinage ratio equivalent
to the bullion ratio. The difficulty with this scheme, even
if it were wholly sufficient, has thus far been in the obstacles
to international agreement. After several international monetary
conferences, in 1867, 1878, and 1881, the project seems
now to have been practically abandoned by all except the most
sanguine. (For a fuller list of authorities on bimetallism, see
</span><SPAN href="#Appendix_I" class="tei tei-ref"><span style="font-size: 90%">Appendix I</span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%">.)
</span></p>
<hr class="page" />
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />