<SPAN name="toc210" id="toc210"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="pdf211" id="pdf211"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="Book_III_Chapter_XV" id="Book_III_Chapter_XV" class="tei tei-anchor"></SPAN>
<h2><span>Chapter XV. Of Money Considered As An Imported Commodity.</span></h2>
<SPAN name="toc212" id="toc212"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 1. Money imported on two modes; as a Commodity, and as a medium of Exchange.</span></h3>
<p>
The degree of progress which we have now made
in the theory of foreign trade puts it in our power to supply
what was previously deficient in our view of the theory
of money; and this, when completed, will in its turn enable
us to conclude the subject of foreign trade.</p>
<p>
Money, or the material of which it is composed, is, in
Great Britain, and in most other countries, a foreign commodity.
Its value and distribution must therefore be regulated,
not by the law of value which obtains in adjacent
places, but by that which is applicable to imported commodities—the
law of international values.</p>
<p>
In the discussion into which we are now about to enter,
I shall use the terms money and the precious metals indiscriminately.
This may be done without leading to any error;
it having been shown that the value of money, when it
consists of the precious metals, or of a paper currency convertible
into them on demand, is entirely governed by the
value of the metals themselves: from which it never permanently
differs, except by the expense of coinage, when
this is paid by the individual and not by the state.</p>
<p>
Money is brought into a country in two different ways.
It is imported (chiefly in the form of bullion) like any other
merchandise, as being an advantageous article of commerce.
It is also imported in its other character of a medium of
exchange, to pay some debt due to the country, either for
goods exported or on any other account. The existence of
these two distinct modes in which money flows into a country,
while other commodities are habitually introduced only
in the first of these modes, occasions somewhat more of complexity
and obscurity than exists in the case of other commodities,
and for this reason only is any special and minute
exposition necessary.</p>
<SPAN name="toc213" id="toc213"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 2. As a commodity, it obeys the same laws of Value as other imported Commodities.</span></h3>
<p>
In so far as the precious metals are imported in the
ordinary way of commerce, their value must depend on the
same causes, and conform to the same laws, as the value of
any other foreign production. It is in this mode chiefly that
gold and silver diffuse themselves from the mining countries
into all other parts of the commercial world. They are the
staple commodities of those countries, or at least are among
their great articles of regular export; and are shipped on
speculation, in the same manner as other exportable commodities.
The quantity, therefore, which a country (say
England) will give of its own produce, for a certain quantity
of bullion, will depend, if we suppose only two countries and
two commodities, upon the demand in England for bullion,
compared with the demand in the mining country (which we
will call the United States<SPAN id="noteref_272" name="noteref_272" href="#note_272"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">272</span></span></SPAN>) for what England has to give.</p>
<p>
The bullion required by England must exactly pay for
the cottons or other English commodities required by the
United States. If, however, we substitute for this simplicity
the degree of complication which really exists, the equation
of international demand must be established not between the
bullion wanted in England and the cottons or broadcloth
wanted in the United States, but between the whole of the
imports of England and the whole of her exports. The demand
in foreign countries for English products must be
brought into equilibrium with the demand in England for
the products of foreign countries; and all foreign commodities,
bullion among the rest, must be exchanged against
English products in such proportions as will, by the effect
they produce on the demand, establish this equilibrium.</p>
<p>
There is nothing in the peculiar nature or uses of the
precious metals which should make them an exception to the
general principles of demand. So far as they are wanted for
purposes of luxury or the arts, the demand increases with
the cheapness, in the same irregular way as the demand for
any other commodity. So far as they are required for
money, the demand increases with the cheapness in a perfectly
regular way, the quantity needed being always in inverse
proportion to the value. This is the only real difference,
in respect to demand, between money and other things.</p>
<p>
Money, then, if imported solely as a merchandise, will,
like other imported commodities, be of lowest value in the
countries for whose exports there is the greatest foreign
demand, and which have themselves the least demand for
foreign commodities. To these two circumstances it is, however,
necessary to add two others, which produce their effect
through cost of carriage. The cost of obtaining bullion is
compounded of two elements; the goods given to purchase
it and the expense of transport; of which last, the bullion
countries will bear a part (though an uncertain part) in the
adjustment of international values. The expense of transport
is partly that of carrying the goods to the bullion countries,
and partly that of bringing back the bullion; both these
items are influenced by the distance from the mines; and
the former is also much affected by the bulkiness of the
goods. Countries whose exportable produce consists of the
finer manufactures obtain bullion, as well as all other foreign
articles, <span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-style: italic">cæteris paribus</span></span>, at less expense than countries which
export nothing but bulky raw produce.</p>
<p>
To be quite accurate, therefore, we must say: The countries
whose exportable productions (1) are most in demand
abroad, and (2) contain greatest value in smallest bulk, (3)
which are nearest to the mines, and (4) which have least demand
for foreign productions, are those in which money
will be of lowest value, or, in other words, in which prices
will habitually range the highest. If we are speaking not
of the value of money, but of its cost (that is, the quantity
of the country's labor which must be expended to obtain it),
we must add (5) to these four conditions of cheapness a fifth
condition, namely, <span class="tei tei-q">“whose productive industry is the most
efficient.”</span> This last, however, does not at all affect the value
of money, estimated in commodities; it affects the general
abundance and facility with which all things, money and
commodities together, can be obtained.<SPAN id="noteref_273" name="noteref_273" href="#note_273"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">273</span></span></SPAN></p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
The accompanying Chart, </span><SPAN href="#Chart_XIV" class="tei tei-ref"><span style="font-size: 90%">No. XIV</span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%">, on the next page, gives
the excess of exports from the United States of gold and silver
coin and bullion over imports, and the excess of imports over
exports. The movement of the line above the horizontal baseline
shows distinctly how largely we have been sending the
precious metals abroad from our mines, simply as a regular
article of export, like merchandise. From 1850 to 1879 the
exports are clearly not in the nature of payments for trade
balances; since it indicates a steady movement out of the
country (with the exception of the first year of the war, when
gold came to this country). The phenomenal increase of specie
exports during the war, and until 1879, was due to the fact
that we had a depreciated paper currency, which sent the
metals out of the country as merchandise. This chart should
be studied in connection with Chart </span><SPAN href="#Chart_XIII" class="tei tei-ref"><span style="font-size: 90%">No. XIII</span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%">.
</span>
<SPAN name="Chart_XIV" id="Chart_XIV" class="tei tei-anchor"></SPAN>
<p></p>
<ANTIMG src="images/chartxiv.png" width-obs="700" height-obs="378" alt="Illustration: Chart XIV." title="Chart XIV. Chart showing the Excess of Exports and Imports of Gold and Silver Coin and Bullion, from and into the United States, from 1835 to 1883. The line when above the base-line shows the excess of exports; when below, the excess of imports." />Chart XIV. <span class="tei tei-hi" style="text-align: center"><span style="font-style: italic">Chart showing the Excess of Exports and Imports of Gold
and Silver Coin and Bullion, from and into the United States, from
1835 to 1883. The line when above the base-line shows the excess of exports; when
below, the excess of imports.</span></span>
<p>
From the preceding considerations, it appears that those
are greatly in error who contend that the value of money,
in countries where it is an imported commodity, must be
entirely regulated by its value in the countries which produce
it; and can not be raised or lowered in any permanent
manner unless some change has taken place in the cost of
production at the mines. On the contrary, any circumstance
which disturbs the equation of international demand with
respect to a particular country not only may, but must,
affect the value of money in that country—its value at the
mines remaining the same. The opening of a new branch
of export trade from England; an increase in the foreign
demand for English products, either by the natural course
of events or by the abrogation of duties; a check to the
demand in England for foreign commodities, by the laying
on of import duties in England or of export duties elsewhere;
these and all other events of similar tendency would
make the imports of England (bullion and other things taken
together) no longer an equivalent for the exports; and the
countries which take her exports would be obliged to offer
their commodities, and bullion among the rest, on cheaper
terms, in order to re-establish the equation of demand; and
thus England would obtain money cheaper, and would acquire
a generally higher range of prices. A country which,
from any of the causes mentioned, gets money cheaper, obtains
all its other imports cheaper likewise.</p>
<p>
It is by no means necessary that the increased demand
for English commodities, which enables England to supply
herself with bullion at a cheaper rate, should be a demand
in the mining countries. England might export nothing
whatever to those countries, and yet might be the country
which obtained bullion from them on the lowest terms, provided
there were a sufficient intensity of demand in other
foreign countries for English goods, which would be paid
for circuitously, with gold and silver from the mining countries.
The whole of its exports are what a country exchanges
against the whole of its imports, and not its exports
and imports to and from any one country.</p>
<hr class="page" />
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />