<SPAN name="toc243" id="toc243"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="pdf244" id="pdf244"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="Book_III_Chapter_XXI" id="Book_III_Chapter_XXI" class="tei tei-anchor"></SPAN>
<h2><span>Chapter XXI. Of Distribution, As Affected By Exchange.</span></h2>
<SPAN name="toc245" id="toc245"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 1. Exchange and money make no Difference in the law of Wages.</span></h3>
<p>
The division of the produce among the three classes,
laborers, capitalists, and landlords, when considered without
any reference to exchange, appeared to depend on certain
general laws. It is fit that we should now consider whether
these same laws still operate, when the distribution takes
place through the complex mechanism of exchange and
money; or whether the properties of the mechanism interfere
with and modify the presiding principles.</p>
<p>
The primary division of the produce of human exertion
and frugality is, as we have seen, into three shares—wages,
profits, and rents; and these shares are portioned out, to the
persons entitled to them, in the form of money and by a
process of exchange; or, rather, the capitalist, with whom in
the usual arrangements of society the produce remains, pays
in money, to the other two sharers, the market value of their
labor and land. If we examine on what the pecuniary value
of labor and the pecuniary value of the use of land depend,
we shall find that it is on the very same causes by which we
found that wages and rent would be regulated if there were
no money and no exchange of commodities.</p>
<p>
It is evident, in the first place, that the law of wages is
not affected by the existence or non-existence of exchange or
money. Wages depend on the ratio between population and
capital [taking into account the nature of a country's industries];
and would do so if all the capital in the world were
the property of one association, or if the capitalists among
whom it is shared maintained each an establishment for the
production of every article consumed in the community, exchange
of commodities having no existence. As the ratio
between capital and population, everywhere but in new colonies,
depends on the strength of the checks by which the
too rapid increase of population is restrained, it may be said,
popularly speaking, that wages depend on the checks to population;
that, when the check is not death by starvation or
disease, wages depend on the prudence of the laboring people;
and that wages in any country are habitually at the
lowest rate to which in that country the laborer will suffer
them to be depressed rather than put a restraint upon multiplication.</p>
<p>
What is here meant, however, by wages, is the laborer's
real scale of comfort; the quantity he obtains of the things
which nature or habit has made necessary or agreeable to
him: wages in the sense in which they are of importance to
the receiver. In the sense in which they are of importance
to the payer, they do not depend exclusively on such simple
principles. Wages in the first sense, the wages on which the
laborer's comfort depends, we will call real wages, or wages
in kind. Wages in the second sense we may be permitted
to call, for the present, money wages; assuming, as it is allowable
to do, that money remains for the time an invariable
standard, no alteration taking place in the conditions under
which the circulating medium itself is produced or obtained.
If money itself undergoes no variation in cost, the money
price of labor is an exact measure of the cost of labor, and
may be made use of as a convenient symbol to express it
[if the efficiency of labor also be supposed to remain the
same].</p>
<p>
The money wages of labor are a compound result of two
elements: first, real wages, or wages in kind, or, in other
words, the quantity which the laborer obtains of the ordinary
articles of consumption; and, secondly, the money prices
of those articles. In all old countries—all countries in which
the increase of population is in any degree checked by the
difficulty of obtaining subsistence—the habitual money price
of labor is that which will just enable the laborers, one
with another, to purchase the commodities without which
they either can not or will not keep up the population at its
customary rate of increase. Their standard of comfort being
given (and by the standard of comfort in a laboring class is
meant that rather than forego which they will abstain from
multiplication), money wages depend on the money price,
and therefore on the cost of production, of the various articles
which the laborers habitually consume: because, if their
wages can not procure them a given quantity of these, their
increase will slacken and their wages rise. Of these articles,
food and other agricultural produce are so much the principal
as to leave little influence to anything else.</p>
<p>
It is at this point that we are enabled to invoke the aid
of the principles which have been laid down in this Third
Part. The cost of production of food and agricultural produce
has been analyzed in a preceding chapter. It depends
on the productiveness of the least fertile land, or of the least
productively employed portion of capital, which the necessities
of society have as yet put in requisition for agricultural
purposes. The cost of production of the food grown in
these least advantageous circumstances determines, as we
have seen, the exchange value and money price of the whole.
In any given state, therefore, of the laborers' habits, their
money wages depend on the productiveness of the least fertile
land, or least productive agricultural capital: on the point
which cultivation has reached in its downward progress—in
its encroachments on the barren lands, and its gradually increased
strain upon the powers of the more fertile. Now,
the force which urges cultivation in this downward course
is the increase of people; while the counter-force, which
checks the descent, is the improvement of agricultural science
and practice, enabling the same soil to yield to the same
labor more ample returns. The costliness of the most costly
part of the produce of cultivation is an exact expression of
the state, at any given moment, of the race which population
and agricultural skill are always running against each
other.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
It will be noted, in this exposition, that Mr. Mill has in view
an old country, with a population so dense that numbers are
always pressing close upon subsistence; that their wages are
so low as to give the laborers little more than the necessary
wants of life. That these are not the economic conditions in
the United States goes without saying. First of all, the margin
of cultivation is high: only soils of high productiveness
are in cultivation, and the returns to labor and capital are, consequently,
very large. High wages are found together with
low prices of food. The existing population is not so numerous
as to require for the cultivation of food any but lands of a
very high grade of fertility. The ability to command a high
reward for labor (as compared with European industries), owing
to the general prevalence of high returns in the United States,
has resulted in the establishment of a higher standard for our
laborers. The standard being relatively so high, there is no
intimate connection between the increase of population here
and the price of food; for, as a rule, wages are not so low that
any change in the cost of producing food would require checks
upon population. There is a considerable margin above necessaries,
in the laborer's real wages in the United States, which
may go for comforts, decencies, and amusements.
</span>
<SPAN name="toc246" id="toc246"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 2. In the law of Rent.</span></h3>
<p>
The degree of productiveness of this extreme margin
is an index to the existing state of the distribution of the
produce among the three classes, of laborers, capitalists, and
landlords. When the demand of an increasing population
for more food can not be satisfied without extending cultivation
to less fertile land, or incurring additional outlay, with
a less proportional return, on land already in cultivation, it is
a necessary condition of this increase of agricultural produce
that the value and price of that produce must first rise. The
price of food will always on the average be such that the
worst land, and the least productive installment of the capital
employed on the better lands, shall just replace the expenses
with the ordinary profit. If the least favored land and capital
just do thus much, all other land and capital will yield an
extra profit, equal to the proceeds of the extra produce due
to their superior productiveness; and this extra profit becomes,
by competition, the prize of the landlords. Exchange
and money, therefore, make no difference in the law of rent:
it is the same as we
originally<SPAN id="noteref_293" name="noteref_293" href="#note_293"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">293</span></span></SPAN> found it. Rent is the extra
return made to agricultural capital when employed with peculiar
advantages; the exact equivalent of what those advantages
enable the producers to economize in the cost of production:
the value and price of the produce being regulated
by the cost of production to those producers who have no
advantages; by the return to that portion of agricultural
capital the circumstances of which are the least favorable.</p>
<SPAN name="toc247" id="toc247"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 3. —Nor in the law of Profits.</span></h3>
<p>
Wages and rent being thus regulated by the same
principles when paid in money, as they would be if apportioned
in kind, it follows that Profits are so likewise. For
the surplus, after replacing wages and paying rent, constitutes
Profits.</p>
<p>
We found, in the last chapter of the Second Book, that
the advances of the capitalist, when analyzed to their ultimate
elements, consist either in the purchase or maintenance
of labor, or in the profits of former capitalists; and that,
therefore, profits in the last resort depend upon the Cost of
Labor, falling as that rises, and rising as it falls. Let us endeavor
to trace more minutely the operation of this law.</p>
<p>
There are two modes in which the Cost of Labor, which
is correctly represented (money being supposed invariable as
well as efficiency) by the money wages of the laborer, may
be increased. The laborer may obtain greater comforts;
wages in kind—real wages—may rise. Or the progress of
population may force down cultivation to inferior soils and
more costly processes; thus raising the cost of production,
the value, and the price, of the chief articles of the laborer's
consumption. On either of these suppositions the rate of
profit will fall.</p>
<p>
If the laborer obtains more abundant commodities only
by reason of their greater cheapness, if he obtains a greater
quantity, but not on the whole a greater cost, real wages
will be increased, but not money wages, and there will be
nothing to affect the rate of profit. But, if he obtains a
greater quantity of commodities of which the cost of production
is not lowered, he obtains a greater cost; his money
wages are higher. The expense of these increased money
wages falls wholly on the capitalist. There are no conceivable
means by which he can shake it off. It may be said—it
used formerly to be said—that he will get rid of it by raising
his price. But this opinion we have already, and more
than once, fully refuted.<SPAN id="noteref_294" name="noteref_294" href="#note_294"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">294</span></span></SPAN></p>
<p>
The doctrine, indeed, that a rise of wages causes an
equivalent rise of prices, is, as we formerly observed, self-contradictory:
for, if it did so, it would not be a rise of
wages; the laborer would get no more of any commodity
than he had before, let his money wages rise ever so much;
a rise of real wages would be an impossibility. This being
equally contrary to reason and to fact, it is evident that a rise
of money wages does not raise prices; that high wages are
not a cause of high prices. A rise of general wages falls on
profits. There is no possible alternative.</p>
<p>
Having disposed of the case in which the increase of
money wages, and of the Cost of Labor, arises from the
laborer's obtaining more ample wages in kind, let us now
suppose it to arise from the increased cost of production of
the things which he consumes, owing to an increase of population
unaccompanied by an equivalent increase of agricultural
skill. The augmented supply required by the population
would not be obtained, unless the price of food rose
sufficiently to remunerate the farmer for the increased cost
of production. The farmer, however, in this case sustains a
twofold disadvantage. He has to carry on his cultivation
under less favorable conditions of productiveness than before.
For this, as it is a disadvantage belonging to him only as a
farmer, and not shared by other employers, he will, on the
general principles of value, be compensated by a rise of the
price of his commodity; indeed, until this rise has taken
place, he will not bring to market the required increase of
produce. But this very rise of price involves him in another
necessity, for which he is not compensated. He must pay
higher money wages to his laborers [if they retain the same
quantity of real wages]. This necessity, being common to
him with all other capitalists, forms no ground for a rise of
price. The price will rise, until it has placed him in as good
a situation, in respect of profits, as other employers of labor;
it will rise so as to indemnify him for the increased labor
which he must now employ in order to produce a given
quantity of food; but the increased wages of that labor are
a burden common to all, and for which no one can be indemnified.
It will be paid wholly from profits.</p>
<p>
Thus we see that increased wages, when common to all
descriptions of productive laborers, and when really representing
a greater Cost of Labor, are always and necessarily
at the expense of profits. And by reversing the cases, we
should find in like manner that diminished wages, when
representing a really diminished Cost of Labor, are equivalent
to a rise of profits. But the opposition of pecuniary
interest thus indicated between the class of capitalists and
that of laborers is to a great extent only apparent. Real
wages are a very different thing from the Cost of Labor, and
are generally highest at the times and places where, from
the easy terms on which the land yields all the produce as
yet required from it, the value and price of food being low,
the cost of labor to the employer, notwithstanding its ample
remuneration, is comparatively cheap, and the rate of profit
consequently high, as at present in the United States. We
thus obtain a full confirmation of our original theorem that
Profits depend on the Cost of Labor: or, to express the
meaning with still greater accuracy, the rate of profit and
the cost of labor vary inversely as one another, and are joint
effects of the same agencies or causes.</p>
<!--book-->
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />