<h2> <SPAN name="article40"></SPAN> High Finance </h2>
<p>I know very little about the Stock Exchange. I know, of
course, that stockbrokers wear very shiny top-hats, which
they remove when they sing “God Save the King,”
as they invariably do in a crisis. When they go out to lunch,
the younger ones leave their top-hats behind them, and take
the air with plastered polls; and after lunch is over, young
and old alike have a round of dominoes before placing
threepence under the coffee-cup and returning to business. If
business is slack, they tell each other jokes, which get into
the papers with some such introduction as, “A good
story going the round of the Stock Exchange.” Probably
it was going the round of the nurseries in 72, but the
stockbrokers have been so busy making Consols go up and down
that they have not been able to listen to it before. Anyway,
the careful man always avoids a good story which is going the
round of the Stock Exchange.</p>
<p>But apart from these minor activities of the City, the
financial world has always been a mystery to me. To this day
I do not understand why Consols go up and down. Perhaps they
only go down now, but there was a time when they would be 78
<sup>1</sup>/<sub>4</sub> in the morning, 78
<sup>1</sup>/<sub>2</sub> after the Stock Exchange had
returned from its coffee, and 78 when it went out to play
dominoes again. When they thudded down to 78, this proved
that the Government had lost the confidence of the country.
But I never heard an explanation of it all which carried any
conviction.</p>
<p>Once I asked a noted financial authority to tell me all about
it in words of one syllable. He did his best. He said it was
“simply a question of supply and demand.” In that
case one would expect umbrellas to go up and down according
to the weather--I mean, of course, the price of umbrellas.
But apparently umbrellas aren’t so sensitive as stocks,
which are the most sensitive things in the world. In the
happy days before the war, when the President of Nicaragua
sent a stiff note to the President of Uruguay, Consols
immediately dropped a quarter of a point. The President of
Uruguay answered, “Sorry, my mistake,” and
Consols went back again. Evidently, several gentlemen, who
would have bought Consols in the ordinary way on that
Thursday, decided to buy Haricot Beans instead, as being, I
suppose, more useful in the event of a war between Nicaragua
and Uruguay. So Consols feeling the neglect, went down. But
on the Friday, as soon as Uruguay had apologized, the
gentlemen who had just sold the Haricot Beans hurried out to
buy Consols, as being quite safe again now that there was no
more chance of war. So Consols went cheerfully up again. You
see?</p>
<p>But the financial problem is getting very much more difficult
than this, The vagaries of Consols, or even of the reputed
gold-mine in which I once had shares--(this is a sad story,
but, fortunately, when they had dropped to six-and-sixpence,
there was a demand for them by a man called Wilkinson, poor
fellow, which arrested the fall just long enough for me to
get out. They are now three a penny, so I hope Wilkinson
found a demand, too)--well, then, even the vagaries of the
West African market are a simple matter compared with the
vagaries of the Exchange. The mystery of the mark, for
instance, is so utterly beyond that, in trying to understand
it, I do not even know where to begin. I see no mental
foothold anywhere.</p>
<p>The mark, we are told, is now worth tuppence-ha’penny.
Why? I mean, who said so? Who is it who arranges these
things? Is it Rockefeller or one of the Geddeses or Samuel
Gompers--a superman of some kind? Or is it a Committee of the
Stock Exchange and Greenwich Observatory? And how does it
decide? Does it put a mark up for auction and see what the
demand is like? Or does it decide on moral grounds? Does it
say contemptuously, “Oh, I should think about
tuppence-ha’penny, and serve ’em dashed well
right for losing the war”?</p>
<p>Let us go slowly, and see if we can make any sense of it.
Suppose that I produce something worth a shilling, something,
that is, which I can sell in this country for a shilling--a
blank verse tragedy, say. Let us suppose also that, having
received the shilling, I propose to buy a bag of nuts. A
German offers me a mark for my tragedy. Now that mark has got
to be spent in Germany by somebody; not, of course,
necessarily by me. I probably hand it to Thomas Cook or his
Son, who gives it to somebody else, who eventually takes it
back to Germany again. Obviously, then, what I have to
consider, when I am offered a mark instead of the customary
shilling for my blank verse, is this: “Can this mark
purchase a similar-sized bag of nuts in
Germany?” If the answer is “Yes,”
then the mark is worth a shilling; if the answer is that it
will only buy a bag of about a fifth of the English size,
then the mark is worth tuppence-ha’penny.</p>
<p>Well, is everything in Germany five times as dear as it is in
England? No. Not by any means. If a mark is regarded
as tuppence-ha’penny, everything is extraordinarily
cheap; much cheaper than in England. Also it occurs to me
suddenly that if this were the way in which the pundits
decided upon the price of the mark and the franc and the
peseta and the cowrie-shell, then the price of living in
every country would be exactly the same, and we should have
nowhere to retire to when the taxes were too high. Which
would be absurd. So we must have done the sum wrong. Let us
try again.</p>
<p>The price of the mark (this is our new theory) depends on the
amount of goods which Germany is exporting. A German offers
me a mark for my tragedy, but if no other German has got
anything to give me, or Thomas Cook or his Son, in exchange
for that mark, then the mark is obviously no good to us. If,
then, we say that the mark is worth tuppence-ha’penny,
we mean that Germany is importing (or buying) five times as
much as she is exporting (or selling). Similarly, when the
rouble was about ten a penny, Russia was importing a hundred
times as much as she was exporting. But she was not importing
anything then because of the blockade. Therefore--no,
it’s no good. You see, we can’t do it. We shall
have to stand about on the Brighton road until one of those
stockbrokers comes by. He will explain it to us.</p>
<p>But perhaps a better man to consult in these matters of High
Finance is the Strong Man whom we see so often upon the
stage. Sometimes he builds bridges, and sometimes he makes
steel, but the one I like best is the one who controls the
markets of the world. He strides to the telephone and says
grimly down it: “Sell Chilled Tomatoes.... No....
Yes... Keep on selling,” and in far-away Nan-Kang-Foo a
man shoots himself. He had too many Chilled Tomatoes--or too
few.</p>
<p>But the Strong Man goes on his way. He is married to a young
and beautiful girl, whom he has adored silently for years. He
has never told her; partly because he thought it would not be
fair to her, partly because he knows it would spoil the play.
He is too busy to see much of her, but sometimes they meet at
dinner, and then he strokes her head and asks her kindly what
she is doing that evening. Probably she is going out with
George B. Pusher. What else could you expect? All the time
when Staunton is buying Tomatoes and Salmon and Tintacks and
Locomotives and Peanuts and lots of things that he
doesn’t really want, George B. Pusher is in attendance
on the Heroine.</p>
<p>There is a terrible scene when Staunton discovers what is
going on. Who is this puppy? George B. Pusher? That settles
it. He will ruin Pusher.</p>
<p>He sells Tomatoes. Pusher hasn’t got any. He buys
Raspberry Jam. Pusher doesn’t want any. Damn the
fellow, he refuses to be ruined. Everybody is shooting
himself except Pusher.</p>
<p>At last. Wire Netting! Why didn’t he think of Wire
Netting before? He buys all the Wire Netting that there is.
Then he sells it all. George R. Pusher is ruined. He comes
round to beg for mercy.</p>
<p>Now, perhaps, if we listen very carefully, we shall
understand how it is all done.</p>
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />