<p>Third Period.—Between 1630 and 1640, or about 1636, the effect of
the discovery of the mines of America, in reducing the value of silver,
appears to have been completed, and the value of that metal seems never to
have sunk lower in proportion to that of corn than it was about that time.
It seems to have risen somewhat in the course of the present century, and
it had probably begun to do so, even some time before the end of the last.</p>
<p>From 1637 to 1700, both inclusive, being the sixty-four last years of the
last century the average price of the quarter of nine bushels of the best
wheat, at Windsor market, appears, from the same accounts, to have been �
2:11:0 1/3, which is only 1s. 0 1/3d. dearer than it had been during the
sixteen years before. But, in the course of these sixty-four years, there
happened two events, which must have produced a much greater scarcity of
corn than what the course of the season is would otherwise have
occasioned, and which, therefore, without supposing any further reduction
in the value of silver, will much more than account for this very small
enhancement of price.</p>
<p>The first of these events was the civil war, which, by discouraging
tillage and interrupting commerce, must have raised the price of corn much
above what the course of the seasons would otherwise have occasioned. It
must have had this effect, more or less, at all the different markets in
the kingdom, but particularly at those in the neighbourhood of London,
which require to be supplied from the greatest distance. In 1648,
accordingly, the price of the best wheat, at Windsor market, appears, from
the same accounts, to have been � 4:5s., and, in 1649, to have been � 4,
the quarter of nine bushels. The excess of those two years above � 2:10s.
(the average price of the sixteen years preceding 1637 is � 3:5s., which,
divided among the sixty four last years of the last century, will alone
very nearly account for that small enhancement of price which seems to
have taken place in them.) These, however, though the highest, are by no
means the only high prices which seem to have been occasioned by the civil
wars.</p>
<p>The second event was the bounty upon the exportation of corn, granted in
1688. The bounty, it has been thought by many people, by encouraging
tillage, may, in a long course of years, have occasioned a greater
abundance, and, consequently, a greater cheapness of corn in the home
market, than what would otherwise have taken place there. How far the
bounty could produce this effect at any time I shall examine hereafter: I
shall only observe at present, that between 1688 and 1700, it had not time
to produce any such effect. During this short period, its only effect must
have been, by encouraging the exportation of the surplus produce of every
year, and thereby hindering the abundance of one year from compensating
the scarcity of another, to raise the price in the home market. The
scarcity which prevailed in England, from 1693 to 1699, both inclusive,
though no doubt principally owing to the badness of the seasons, and,
therefore, extending through a considerable part of Europe, must have been
somewhat enhanced by the bounty. In 1699, accordingly, the further
exportation of corn was prohibited for nine months.</p>
<p>There was a third event which occurred in the course of the same period,
and which, though it could not occasion any scarcity of corn, nor,
perhaps, any augmentation in the real quantity of silver which was usually
paid for it, must necessarily have occasioned some augmentation in the
nominal sum. This event was the great debasement of the silver coin, by
clipping and wearing. This evil had begun in the reign of Charles II. and
had gone on continually increasing till 1695; at which time, as we may
learn from Mr Lowndes, the current silver coin was, at an average, near
five-and-twenty per cent. below its standard value. But the nominal sum
which constitutes the market price of every commodity is necessarily
regulated, not so much by the quantity of silver, which, according to the
standard, ought to be contained in it, as by that which, it is found by
experience, actually is contained in it. This nominal sum, therefore, is
necessarily higher when the coin is much debased by clipping and wearing,
than when near to its standard value.</p>
<p>In the course of the present century, the silver coin has not at any time
been more below its standard weight than it is at present. But though very
much defaced, its value has been kept up by that of the gold coin, for
which it is exchanged. For though, before the late recoinage, the gold
coin was a good deal defaced too, it was less so than the silver. In 1695,
on the contrary, the value of the silver coin was not kept up by the gold
coin; a guinea then commonly exchanging for thirty shillings of the worn
and clipt silver. Before the late recoinage of the gold, the price of
silver bullion was seldom higher than five shillings and sevenpence an
ounce, which is but fivepence above the mint price. But in 1695, the
common price of silver bullion was six shillings and fivepence an ounce,
{Lowndes's Essay on the Silver Coin, 68.} which is fifteen pence above the
mint price. Even before the late recoinage of the gold, therefore, the
coin, gold and silver together, when compared with silver bullion, was not
supposed to be more than eight per cent. below its standard value, In
1695, on the contrary, it had been supposed to be near five-and-twenty per
cent. below that value. But in the beginning of the present century, that
is, immediately after the great recoinage in King William's time, the
greater part of the current silver coin must have been still nearer to its
standard weight than it is at present. In the course of the present
century, too, there has been no great public calamity, such as a civil
war, which could either discourage tillage, or interrupt the interior
commerce of the country. And though the bounty which has taken place
through the greater part of this century, must always raise the price of
corn somewhat higher than it otherwise would be in the actual state of
tillage; yet, as in the course of this century, the bounty has had full
time to produce all the good effects commonly imputed to it to encourage
tillage, and thereby to increase the quantity of corn in the home market,
it may, upon the principles of a system which I shall explain and examine
hereafter, be supposed to have done something to lower the price of that
commodity the one way, as well as to raise it the other. It is by many
people supposed to have done more. In the sixty-four years of the present
century, accordingly, the average price of the quarter of nine bushels of
the best wheat, at Windsor market, appears, by the accounts of Eton
college, to have been � 2:0:6 10/32, which is about ten shillings and
sixpence, or more than five-and-twenty percent. cheaper than it had been
during the sixty-four last years of the last century; and about nine
shillings and sixpence cheaper than it had been during the sixteen years
preceding 1636, when the discovery of the abundant mines of America may be
supposed to have produced its full effect; and about one shilling cheaper
than it had been in the twenty-six years preceding 1620, before that
discovery can well be supposed to have produced its full effect. According
to this account, the average price of middle wheat, during these
sixty-four first years of the present century, comes out to have been
about thirty-two shillings the quarter of eight bushels.</p>
<p>The value of silver, therefore, seems to have risen somewhat in proportion
to that of corn during the course of the present century, and it had
probably begun to do so even some time before the end of the last.</p>
<p>In 1687, the price of the quarter of nine bushels of the best wheat, at
Windsor market, was � 1:5:2, the lowest price at which it had ever been
from 1595.</p>
<p>In 1688, Mr Gregory King, a man famous for his knowledge in matters of
this kind, estimated the average price of wheat, in years of moderate
plenty, to be to the grower 3s. 6d. the bushel, or eight-and-twenty
shillings the quarter. The grower's price I understand to be the same with
what is sometimes called the contract price, or the price at which a
farmer contracts for a certain number of years to deliver a certain
quantity of corn to a dealer. As a contract of this kind saves the farmer
the expense and trouble of marketing, the contract price is generally
lower than what is supposed to be the average market price. Mr King had
judged eight-and-twenty shillings the quarter to be at that time the
ordinary contract price in years of moderate plenty. Before the scarcity
occasioned by the late extraordinary course of bad seasons, it was, I have
been assured, the ordinary contract price in all common years.</p>
<p>In 1688 was granted the parliamentary bounty upon the exportation of corn.
The country gentlemen, who then composed a still greater proportion of the
legislature than they do at present, had felt that the money price of corn
was falling. The bounty was an expedient to raise it artificially to the
high price at which it had frequently been sold in the times of Charles I.
and II. It was to take place, therefore, till wheat was so high as
fortyeight shillings the quarter; that is, twenty shillings, or 5-7ths
dearer than Mr King had, in that very year, estimated the grower's price
to be in times of moderate plenty. If his calculations deserve any part of
the reputation which they have obtained very universally, eight-and-forty
shillings the quarter was a price which, without some such expedient as
the bounty, could not at that time be expected, except in years of
extraordinary scarcity. But the government of King William was not then
fully settled. It was in no condition to refuse anything to the country
gentlemen, from whom it was, at that very time, soliciting the first
establishment of the annual land-tax.</p>
<p>The value of silver, therefore, in proportion to that of corn, had
probably risen somewhat before the end of the last century; and it seems
to have continued to do so during the course of the greater part of the
present, though the necessary operation of the bounty must have hindered
that rise from being so sensible as it otherwise would have been in the
actual state of tillage.</p>
<p>In plentiful years, the bounty, by occasioning an extraordinary
exportation, necessarily raises the price of corn above what it otherwise
would be in those years. To encourage tillage, by keeping up the price of
corn, even in the most plentiful years, was the avowed end of the
institution.</p>
<p>In years of great scarcity, indeed, the bounty has generally been
suspended. It must, however, have had some effect upon the prices of many
of those years. By the extraordinary exportation which it occasions in
years of plenty, it must frequently hinder the plenty of one year from
compensating the scarcity of another.</p>
<p>Both in years of plenty and in years of scarcity, therefore, the bounty
raises the price of corn above what it naturally would be in the actual
state of tillage. If during the sixty-four first years of the present
century, therefore, the average price has been lower than during the
sixty-four last years of the last century, it must, in the same state of
tillage, have been much more so, had it not been for this operation of the
bounty.</p>
<p>But, without the bounty, it may be said the state of tillage would not
have been the same. What may have been the effects of this institution
upon the agriculture of the country, I shall endeavour to explain
hereafter, when I come to treat particularly of bounties. I shall only
observe at present, that this rise in the value of silver, in proportion
to that of corn, has not been peculiar to England. It has been observed to
have taken place in France during the same period, and nearly in the same
proportion, too, by three very faithful, diligent, and laborious
collectors of the prices of corn, Mr Dupr� de St Maur, Mr Messance, and
the author of the Essay on the Police of Grain. But in France, till 1764,
the exportation of grain was by law prohibited; and it is somewhat
difficult to suppose, that nearly the same diminution of price which took
place in one country, notwithstanding this prohibition, should, in
another, be owing to the extraordinary encouragement given to exportation.</p>
<p>It would be more proper, perhaps, to consider this variation in the
average money price of corn as the effect rather of some gradual rise in
the real value of silver in the European market, than of any fall in the
real average value of corn. Corn, it has already been observed, is, at
distant periods of time, a more accurate measure of value than either
silver or, perhaps, any other commodity. When, after the discovery of the
abundant mines of America, corn rose to three and four times its former
money price, this change was universally ascribed, not to any rise in the
real value of corn, but to a fall in the real value of silver. If, during
the sixty-four first years of the present century, therefore, the average
money price of corn has fallen somewhat below what it had been during the
greater part of the last century, we should, in the same manner, impute
this change, not to any fall in the real value of corn, but to some rise
in the real value of silver in the European market.</p>
<p>The high price of corn during these ten or twelve years past, indeed, has
occasioned a suspicion that the real value of silver still continues to
fall in the European market. This high price of corn, however, seems
evidently to have been the effect of the extraordinary unfavourableness of
the seasons, and ought, therefore, to be regarded, not as a permanent, but
as a transitory and occasional event. The seasons, for these ten or twelve
years past, have been unfavourable through the greater part of Europe; and
the disorders of Poland have very much increased the scarcity in all those
countries, which, in dear years, used to be supplied from that market. So
long a course of bad seasons, though not a very common event, is by no
means a singular one; and whoever has inquired much into the history of
the prices of corn in former times, will be at no loss to recollect
several other examples of the same kind. Ten years of extraordinary
scarcity, besides, are not more wonderful than ten years of extraordinary
plenty. The low price of corn, from 1741 to 1750, both inclusive, may very
well be set in opposition to its high price during these last eight or ten
years. From 1741 to 1750, the average price of the quarter of nine bushels
of the best wheat, at Windsor market, it appears from the accounts of Eton
college, was only � 1:13:9 4/5, which is nearly 6s.3d. below the average
price of the sixty-four first years of the present century. The average
price of the quarter of eight bushels of middle wheat comes out, according
to this account, to have been, during these ten years, only � 1:6:8.</p>
<p>Between 1741 and 1750, however, the bounty must have hindered the price of
corn from falling so low in the home market as it naturally would have
done. During these ten years, the quantity of all sorts of grain exported,
it appears from the custom-house books, amounted to no less than 8,029,156
quarters, one bushel. The bounty paid for this amounted to �
1,514,962:17:4 1/2. In 1749, accordingly, Mr Pelham, at that time prime
minister, observed to the house of commons, that, for the three years
preceding, a very extraordinary sum had been paid as bounty for the
exportation of corn. He had good reason to make this observation, and in
the following year he might have had still better. In that single year,
the bounty paid amounted to no less than � 324,176:10:6. {See Tracts on
the Corn Trade, Tract 3,} It is unnecessary to observe how much this
forced exportation must have raised the price of corn above what it
otherwise would have been in the home market.</p>
<p>At the end of the accounts annexed to this chapter the reader will find
the particular account of those ten years separated from the rest. He will
find there, too, the particular account of the preceding ten years, of
which the average is likewise below, though not so much below, the general
average of the sixty-four first years of the century. The year 1740,
however, was a year of extraordinary scarcity. These twenty years
preceding 1750 may very well be set in opposition to the twenty preceding
1770. As the former were a good deal below the general average of the
century, notwithstanding the intervention of one or two dear years; so the
latter have been a good deal above it, notwithstanding the intervention of
one or two cheap ones, of 1759, for example. If the former have not been
as much below the general average as the latter have been above it, we
ought probably to impute it to the bounty. The change has evidently been
too sudden to be ascribed to any change in the value of silver, which is
always slow and gradual. The suddenness of the effect can be accounted for
only by a cause which can operate suddenly, the accidental variations of
the seasons.</p>
<p>The money price of labour in Great Britain has, indeed, risen during the
course of the present century. This, however, seems to be the effect, not
so much of any diminution in the value of silver in the European market,
as of an increase in the demand for labour in Great Britain, arising from
the great, and almost universal prosperity of the country. In France, a
country not altogether so prosperous, the money price of labour has, since
the middle of the last century, been observed to sink gradually with the
average money price of corn. Both in the last century and in the present,
the day wages of common labour are there said to have been pretty
uniformly about the twentieth part of the average price of the septier of
wheat; a measure which contains a little more than four Winchester
bushels. In Great Britain, the real recompence of labour, it has already
been shewn, the real quantities of the necessaries and conveniencies of
life which are given to the labourer, has increased considerably during
the course of the present century. The rise in its money price seems to
have been the effect, not of any diminution of the value of silver in the
general market of Europe, but of a rise in the real price of labour, in
the particular market of Great Britain, owing to the peculiarly happy
circumstances of the country.</p>
<p>For some time after the first discovery of America, silver would continue
to sell at its former, or not much below its former price. The profits of
mining would for some time be very great, and much above their natural
rate. Those who imported that metal into Europe, however, would soon find
that the whole annual importation could not be disposed of at this high
price. Silver would gradually exchange for a smaller and a smaller
quantity of goods. Its price would sink gradually lower and lower, till it
fell to its natural price; or to what was just sufficient to pay,
according to their natural rates, the wages of the labour, the profits of
the stock, and the rent of the land, which must be paid in order to bring
it from the mine to the market. In the greater part of the silver mines of
Peru, the tax of the king of Spain, amounting to a tenth of the gross
produce, eats up, it has already been observed, the whole rent of the
land. This tax was originally a half; it soon afterwards fell to a third,
then to a fifth, and at last to a tenth, at which late it still continues.
In the greater part of the silver mines of Peru, this, it seems, is all
that remains, after replacing the stock of the undertaker of the work,
together with its ordinary profits; and it seems to be universally
acknowledged that these profits, which were once very high, are now as low
as they can well be, consistently with carrying on the works.</p>
<p>The tax of the king of Spain was reduced to a fifth of the registered
silver in 1504 {Solorzano, vol, ii.}, one-and-forty years before 1545, the
date of the discovery of the mines of Potosi. In the course of ninety
years, or before 1636, these mines, the most fertile in all America, had
time sufficient to produce their full effect, or to reduce the value of
silver in the European market as low as it could well fall, while it
continued to pay this tax to the king of Spain. Ninety years is time
sufficient to reduce any commodity, of which there is no monopoly, to its
natural price, or to the lowest price at which, while it pays a particular
tax, it can continue to be sold for any considerable time together.</p>
<p>The price of silver in the European market might, perhaps, have fallen
still lower, and it might have become necessary either to reduce the tax
upon it, not only to one-tenth, as in 1736, but to one twentieth, in the
same manner as that upon gold, or to give up working the greater part of
the American mines which are now wrought. The gradual increase of the
demand for silver, or the gradual enlargement of the market for the
produce of the silver mines of America, is probably the cause which has
prevented this from happening, and which has not only kept up the value of
silver in the European market, but has perhaps even raised it somewhat
higher than it was about the middle of the last century.</p>
<p>Since the first discovery of America, the market for the produce of its
silver mines has been growing gradually more and more extensive.</p>
<p>First, the market of Europe has become gradually more and more extensive.
Since the discovery of America, the greater part of Europe has been much
improved. England, Holland, France, and Germany; even Sweden, Denmark, and
Russia, have all advanced considerably, both in agriculture and in
manufactures. Italy seems not to have gone backwards. The fall of Italy
preceded the conquest of Peru. Since that time it seems rather to have
recovered a little. Spain and Portugal, indeed, are supposed to have gone
backwards. Portugal, however, is but a very small part of Europe, and the
declension of Spain is not, perhaps, so great as is commonly imagined. In
the beginning of the sixteenth century, Spain was a very poor country,
even in comparison with France, which has been so much improved since that
time. It was the well known remark of the emperor Charles V. who had
travelled so frequently through both countries, that every thing abounded
in France, but that every thing was wanting in Spain. The increasing
produce of the agriculture and manufactures of Europe must necessarily
have required a gradual increase in the quantity of silver coin to
circulate it; and the increasing number of wealthy individuals must have
required the like increase in the quantity of their plate and other
ornaments of silver.</p>
<p>Secondly, America is itself a new market, for the produce of its own
silver mines; and as its advances in agriculture, industry, and
population, are much more rapid than those of the most thriving countries
in Europe, its demand must increase much more rapidly. The English
colonies are altogether a new market, which, partly for coin, and partly
for plate, requires a continual augmenting supply of silver through a
great continent where there never was any demand before. The greater part,
too, of the Spanish and Portuguese colonies, are altogether new markets.
New Granada, the Yucatan, Paraguay, and the Brazils, were, before
discovered by the Europeans, inhabited by savage nations, who had neither
arts nor agriculture. A considerable degree of both has now been
introduced into all of them. Even Mexico and Peru, though they cannot be
considered as altogether new markets, are certainly much more extensive
ones than they ever were before. After all the wonderful tales which have
been published concerning the splendid state of those countries in ancient
times, whoever reads, with any degree of sober judgment, the history of
their first discovery and conquest, will evidently discern that, in arts,
agriculture, and commerce, their inhabitants were much more ignorant than
the Tartars of the Ukraine are at present. Even the Peruvians, the more
civilized nation of the two, though they made use of gold and silver as
ornaments, had no coined money of any kind. Their whole commerce was
carried on by barter, and there was accordingly scarce any division of
labour among them. Those who cultivated the ground, were obliged to build
their own houses, to make their own household furniture, their own
clothes, shoes, and instruments of agriculture. The few artificers among
them are said to have been all maintained by the sovereign, the nobles,
and the priests, and were probably their servants or slaves. All the
ancient arts of Mexico and Peru have never furnished one single
manufacture to Europe. The Spanish armies, though they scarce ever
exceeded five hundred men, and frequently did not amount to half that
number, found almost everywhere great difficulty in procuring subsistence.
The famines which they are said to have occasioned almost wherever they
went, in countries, too, which at the same time are represented as very
populous and well cultivated, sufficiently demonstrate that the story of
this populousness and high cultivation is in a great measure fabulous. The
Spanish colonies are under a government in many respects less favourable
to agriculture, improvement, and population, than that of the English
colonies. They seem, however, to be advancing in all those much more
rapidly than any country in Europe. In a fertile soil and happy climate,
the great abundance and cheapness of land, a circumstance common to all
new colonies, is, it seems, so great an advantage, as to compensate many
defects in civil government. Frezier, who visited Peru in 1713, represents
Lima as containing between twenty-five and twenty-eight thousand
inhabitants. Ulloa, who resided in the same country between 1740 and 1746,
represents it as containing more than fifty thousand. The difference in
their accounts of the populousness of several other principal towns of
Chili and Peru is nearly the same; and as there seems to be no reason to
doubt of the good information of either, it marks an increase which is
scarce inferior to that of the English colonies. America, therefore, is a
new market for the produce of its own silver mines, of which the demand
must increase much more rapidly than that of the most thriving country in
Europe.</p>
<p>Thirdly, the East Indies is another market for the produce of the silver
mines of America, and a market which, from the time of the first discovery
of those mines, has been continually taking off a greater and a greater
quantity of silver. Since that time, the direct trade between America and
the East Indies, which is carried on by means of the Acapulco ships, has
been continually augmenting, and the indirect intercourse by the way of
Europe has been augmenting in a still greater proportion. During the
sixteenth century, the Portuguese were the only European nation who
carried on any regular trade to the East Indies. In the last years of that
century, the Dutch began to encroach upon this monopoly, and in a few
years expelled them from their principal settlements in India. During the
greater part of the last century, those two nations divided the most
considerable part of the East India trade between them; the trade of the
Dutch continually augmenting in a still greater proportion than that of
the Portuguese declined. The English and French carried on some trade with
India in the last century, but it has been greatly augmented in the course
of the present. The East India trade of the Swedes and Danes began in the
course of the present century. Even the Muscovites now trade regularly
with China, by a sort of caravans which go over land through Siberia and
Tartary to Pekin. The East India trade of all these nations, if we except
that of the French, which the last war had well nigh annihilated, has been
almost continually augmenting. The increasing consumptions of East India
goods in Europe is, it seems, so great, as to afford a gradual increase of
employment to them all. Tea, for example, was a drug very little used in
Europe, before the middle of the last century. At present, the value of
the tea annually imported by the English East India company, for the use
of their own countrymen, amounts to more than a million and a half a year;
and even this is not enough; a great deal more being constantly smuggled
into the country from the ports of Holland, from Gottenburgh in Sweden,
and from the coast of France, too, as long as the French East India
company was in prosperity. The consumption of the porcelain of China, of
the spiceries of the Moluccas, of the piece goods of Bengal, and of
innumerable other articles, has increased very nearly in a like
proportion. The tonnage, accordingly, of all the European shipping
employed in the East India trade, at any one time during the last century,
was not, perhaps, much greater than that of the English East India company
before the late reduction of their shipping.</p>
<p>But in the East Indies, particularly in China and Indostan, the value of
the precious metals, when the Europeans first began to trade to those
countries, was much higher than in Europe; and it still continues to be
so. In rice countries, which generally yield two, sometimes three crops in
the year, each of them more plentiful than any common crop of corn, the
abundance of food must be much greater than in any corn country of equal
extent. Such countries are accordingly much more populous. In them, too,
the rich, having a greater superabundance of food to dispose of beyond
what they themselves can consume, have the means of purchasing a much
greater quantity of the labour of other people. The retinue of a grandee
in China or Indostan accordingly is, by all accounts, much more numerous
and splendid than that of the richest subjects in Europe. The same
superabundance of food, of which they have the disposal, enables them to
give a greater quantity of it for all those singular and rare productions
which nature furnishes but in very small quantities; such as the precious
metals and the precious stones, the great objects of the competition of
the rich. Though the mines, therefore, which supplied the Indian market,
had been as abundant as those which supplied the European, such
commodities would naturally exchange for a greater quantity of food in
India than in Europe. But the mines which supplied the Indian market with
the precious metals seem to have been a good deal less abundant, and those
which supplied it with the precious stones a good deal more so, than the
mines which supplied the European. The precious metals, therefore, would
naturally exchange in India for a somewhat greater quantity of the
precious stones, and for a much greater quantity of food than in Europe.
The money price of diamonds, the greatest of all superfluities, would be
somewhat lower, and that of food, the first of all necessaries, a great
deal lower in the one country than in the other. But the real price of
labour, the real quantity of the necessaries of life which is given to the
labourer, it has already been observed, is lower both in China and
Indostan, the two great markets of India, than it is through the greater
part of Europe. The wages of the labourer will there purchase a smaller
quantity of food: and as the money price of food is much lower in India
than in Europe, the money price of labour is there lower upon a double
account; upon account both of the small quantity of food which it will
purchase, and of the low price of that food. But in countries of equal art
and industry, the money price of the greater part of manufactures will be
in proportion to the money price of labour; and in manufacturing art and
industry, China and Indostan, though inferior, seem not to be much
inferior to any part of Europe. The money price of the greater part of
manufactures, therefore, will naturally be much lower in those great
empires than it is anywhere in Europe. Through the greater part of Europe,
too, the expense of land-carriage increases very much both the real and
nominal price of most manufactures. It costs more labour, and therefore
more money, to bring first the materials, and afterwards the complete
manufacture to market. In China and Indostan, the extent and variety of
inland navigations save the greater part of this labour, and consequently
of this money, and thereby reduce still lower both the real and the
nominal price of the greater part of their manufactures. Upon all these
accounts, the precious metals are a commodity which it always has been,
and still continues to be, extremely advantageous to carry from Europe to
India. There is scarce any commodity which brings a better price there; or
which, in proportion to the quantity of labour and commodities which it
costs in Europe, will purchase or command a greater quantity of labour and
commodities in India. It is more advantageous, too, to carry silver
thither than gold; because in China, and the greater part of the other
markets of India, the proportion between fine silver and fine gold is but
as ten, or at most as twelve to one; whereas in Europe it is as fourteen
or fifteen to one. In China, and the greater part of the other markets of
India, ten, or at most twelve ounces of silver, will purchase an ounce of
gold; in Europe, it requires from fourteen to fifteen ounces. In the
cargoes, therefore, of the greater part of European ships which sail to
India, silver has generally been one of the most valuable articles. It is
the most valuable article in the Acapulco ships which sail to Manilla. The
silver of the new continent seems, in this manner, to be one of the
principal commodities by which the commerce between the two extremities of
the old one is carried on; and it is by means of it, in a great measure,
that those distant parts of the world are connected with one another.</p>
<p>In order to supply so very widely extended a market, the quantity of
silver annually brought from the mines must not only be sufficient to
support that continued increase, both of coin and of plate, which is
required in all thriving countries; but to repair that continual waste and
consumption of silver which takes place in all countries where that metal
is used.</p>
<p>The continual consumption of the precious metals in coin by wearing, and
in plate both by wearing and cleaning, is very sensible; and in
commodities of which the use is so very widely extended, would alone
require a very great annual supply. The consumption of those metals in
some particular manufactures, though it may not perhaps be greater upon
the whole than this gradual consumption, is, however, much more sensible,
as it is much more rapid. In the manufactures of Birmingham alone, the
quantity of gold and silver annually employed in gilding and plating, and
thereby disqualified from ever afterwards appearing in the shape of those
metals, is said to amount to more than fifty thousand pounds sterling. We
may from thence form some notion how great must be the annual consumption
in all the different parts of the world, either in manufactures of the
same kind with those of Birmingham, or in laces, embroideries, gold and
silver stuffs, the gilding of books, furniture, etc. A considerable
quantity, too, must be annually lost in transporting those metals from one
place to another both by sea and by land. In the greater part of the
governments of Asia, besides, the almost universal custom of concealing
treasures in the bowels of the earth, of which the knowledge frequently
dies with the person who makes the concealment, must occasion the loss of
a still greater quantity.</p>
<p>The quantity of gold and silver imported at both Cadiz and Lisbon
(including not only what comes under register, but what may be supposed to
be smuggled) amounts, according to the best accounts, to about six
millions sterling a-year.</p>
<p>According to Mr Meggens {Postscript to the Universal Merchant p. 15 and
16. This postscript was not printed till 1756, three years after the
publication of the book, which has never had a second edition. The
postscript is, therefore, to be found in few copies; it corrects several
errors in the book.}, the annual importation of the precious metals into
Spain, at an average of six years, viz. from 1748 to 1753, both inclusive,
and into Portugal, at an average of seven years, viz. from 1747 to 1753,
both inclusive, amounted in silver to 1,101,107 pounds weight, and in gold
to 49,940 pounds weight. The silver, at sixty two shillings the pound
troy, amounts to � 3,413,431:10s. sterling. The gold, at forty-four
guineas and a half the pound troy, amounts to � 2,333,446:14s. sterling.
Both together amount to � 5,746,878:4s. sterling. The account of what was
imported under register, he assures us, is exact. He gives us the detail
of the particular places from which the gold and silver were brought, and
of the particular quantity of each metal, which, according to the
register, each of them afforded. He makes an allowance, too, for the
quantity of each metal which, he supposes, may have been smuggled. The
great experience of this judicious merchant renders his opinion of
considerable weight.</p>
<p>According to the eloquent, and sometimes well-informed, author of the
Philosophical and Political History of the Establishment of the Europeans
in the two Indies, the annual importation of registered gold and silver
into Spain, at an average of eleven years, viz. from 1754 to 1764, both
inclusive, amounted to 13,984,185 3/5 piastres of ten reals. On account of
what may have been smuggled, however, the whole annual importation, he
supposes, may have amounted to seventeen millions of piastres, which, at
4s. 6d. the piastre, is equal to � 3,825,000 sterling. He gives the
detail, too, of the particular places from which the gold and silver were
brought, and of the particular quantities of each metal, which according
to the register, each of them afforded. He informs us, too, that if we
were to judge of the quantity of gold annually imported from the Brazils
to Lisbon, by the amount of the tax paid to the king of Portugal, which it
seems, is one-fifth of the standard metal, we might value it at eighteen
millions of cruzadoes, or forty-five millions of French livres, equal to
about twenty millions sterling. On account of what may have been smuggled,
however, we may safely, he says, add to this sum an eighth more, or �
250,000 sterling, so that the whole will amount to � 2,250,000 sterling.
According to this account, therefore, the whole annual importation of the
precious metals into both Spain and Portugal, mounts to about � 6,075,000
sterling.</p>
<p>Several other very well authenticated, though manuscript accounts, I have
been assured, agree in making this whole annual importation amount, at an
average, to about six millions sterling; sometimes a little more,
sometimes a little less.</p>
<p>The annual importation of the precious metals into Cadiz and Lisbon,
indeed, is not equal to the whole annual produce of the mines of America.
Some part is sent annually by the Acapulco ships to Manilla; some part is
employed in a contraband trade, which the Spanish colonies carry on with
those of other European nations; and some part, no doubt, remains in the
country. The mines of America, besides, are by no means the only gold and
silver mines in the world. They, are, however, by far the most abundant.
The produce of all the other mines which are known is insignificant, it is
acknowledged, in comparison with their's; and the far greater part of
their produce, it is likewise acknowledged, is annually imported into
Cadiz and Lisbon. But the consumption of Birmingham alone, at the rate of
fifty thousand pounds a-year, is equal to the hundred-and-twentieth part
of this annual importation, at the rate of six millions a-year. The whole
annual consumption of gold and silver, therefore, in all the different
countries of the world where those metals are used, may, perhaps, be
nearly equal to the whole annual produce. The remainder may be no more
than sufficient to supply the increasing demand of all thriving countries.
It may even have fallen so far short of this demand, as somewhat to raise
the price of those metals in the European market.</p>
<p>The quantity of brass and iron annually brought from the mine to the
market, is out of all proportion greater than that of gold and silver. We
do not, however, upon this account, imagine that those coarse metals are
likely to multiply beyond the demand, or to become gradually cheaper and
cheaper. Why should we imagine that the precious metals are likely to do
so? The coarse metals, indeed, though harder, are put to much harder uses,
and, as they are of less value, less care is employed in their
preservation. The precious metals, however, are not necessarily immortal
any more than they, but are liable, too, to be lost, wasted, and consumed,
in a great variety of ways.</p>
<p>The price of all metals, though liable to slow and gradual variations,
varies less from year to year than that of almost any other part of the
rude produce of land: and the price of the precious metals is even less
liable to sudden variations than that of the coarse ones. The durableness
of metals is the foundation of this extraordinary steadiness of price. The
corn which was brought to market last year will be all, or almost all,
consumed, long before the end of this year. But some part of the iron
which was brought from: the mine two or three hundred years ago, may be
still in use, and, perhaps, some part of the gold which was brought from
it two or three thousand years ago. The different masses of corn, which,
in different years, must supply the consumption of the world, will always
be nearly in proportion to the respective produce of those different
years. But the proportion between the different masses of iron which may
be in use in two different years, will be very little affected by any
accidental difference in the produce of the iron mines of those two years;
and the proportion between the masses of gold will be still less affected
by any such difference in the produce of the gold mines. Though the
produce of the greater part of metallic mines, therefore, varies, perhaps,
still more from year to year than that of the greater part of corn fields,
those variations have not the same effect upon the price of the one
species of commodities as upon that of the other.</p>
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />