<SPAN name="link2HCH0014" id="link2HCH0014"> </SPAN>
<h2> CHAPTER III. OF THE ACCUMULATION OF CAPITAL, OR OF PRODUCTIVE AND UNPRODUCTIVE LABOUR. </h2>
<p>There is one sort of labour which adds to the value of the subject upon
which it is bestowed; there is another which has no such effect. The
former as it produces a value, may be called productive, the latter,
unproductive labour. {Some French authors of great learning and ingenuity
have used those words in a different sense. In the last chapter of the
fourth book, I shall endeavour to shew that their sense is an improper
one.} Thus the labour of a manufacturer adds generally to the value of the
materials which he works upon, that of his own maintenance, and of his
master's profit. The labour of a menial servant, on the contrary, adds to
the value of nothing. Though the manufacturer has his wages advanced to
him by his master, he in reality costs him no expense, the value of those
wages being generally restored, together with a profit, in the improved
value of the subject upon which his labour is bestowed. But the
maintenance of a menial servant never is restored. A man grows rich by
employing a multitude of manufacturers; he grows poor by maintaining a
multitude or menial servants. The labour of the latter, however, has its
value, and deserves its reward as well as that of the former. But the
labour of the manufacturer fixes and realizes itself in some particular
subject or vendible commodity, which lasts for some time at least after
that labour is past. It is, as it were, a certain quantity of labour
stocked and stored up, to be employed, if necessary, upon some other
occasion. That subject, or, what is the same thing, the price of that
subject, can afterwards, if necessary, put into motion a quantity of
labour equal to that which had originally produced it. The labour of the
menial servant, on the contrary, does not fix or realize itself in any
particular subject or vendible commodity. His services generally perish in
the very instant of their performance, and seldom leave any trace of value
behind them, for which an equal quantity of service could afterwards be
procured.</p>
<p>The labour of some of the most respectable orders in the society is, like
that of menial servants, unproductive of any value, and does not fix or
realize itself in any permanent subject, or vendible commodity, which
endures after that labour is past, and for which an equal quantity of
labour could afterwards be procured. The sovereign, for example, with all
the officers both of justice and war who serve under him, the whole army
and navy, are unproductive labourers. They are the servants of the public,
and are maintained by a part of the annual produce of the industry of
other people. Their service, how honourable, how useful, or how necessary
soever, produces nothing for which an equal quantity of service can
afterwards be procured. The protection, security, and defence, of the
commonwealth, the effect of their labour this year, will not purchase its
protection, security, and defence, for the year to come. In the same class
must be ranked, some both of the gravest and most important, and some of
the most frivolous professions; churchmen, lawyers, physicians, men of
letters of all kinds; players, buffoons, musicians, opera-singers,
opera-dancers, etc. The labour of the meanest of these has a certain
value, regulated by the very same principles which regulate that of every
other sort of labour; and that of the noblest and most useful, produces
nothing which could afterwards purchase or procure an equal quantity of
labour. Like the declamation of the actor, the harangue of the orator, or
the tune of the musician, the work of all of them perishes in the very
instant of its production.</p>
<p>Both productive and unproductive labourers, and those who do not labour at
all, are all equally maintained by the annual produce of the land and
labour of the country. This produce, how great soever, can never be
infinite, but must have certain limits. According, therefore, as a smaller
or greater proportion of it is in any one year employed in maintaining
unproductive hands, the more in the one case, and the less in the other,
will remain for the productive, and the next year's produce will be
greater or smaller accordingly; the whole annual produce, if we except the
spontaneous productions of the earth, being the effect of productive
labour.</p>
<p>Though the whole annual produce of the land and labour of every country is
no doubt ultimately destined for supplying the consumption of its
inhabitants, and for procuring a revenue to them; yet when it first comes
either from the ground, or from the hands of the productive labourers, it
naturally divides itself into two parts. One of them, and frequently the
largest, is, in the first place, destined for replacing a capital, or for
renewing the provisions, materials, and finished work, which had been
withdrawn from a capital; the other for constituting a revenue either to
the owner of this capital, as the profit of his stock, or to some other
person, as the rent of his land. Thus, of the produce of land, one part
replaces the capital of the farmer; the other pays his profit and the rent
of the landlord; and thus constitutes a revenue both to the owner of this
capital, as the profits of his stock, and to some other person as the rent
of his land. Of the produce of a great manufactory, in the same manner,
one part, and that always the largest, replaces the capital of the
undertaker of the work; the other pays his profit, and thus constitutes a
revenue to the owner of this capital.</p>
<p>That part of the annual produce of the land and labour of any country
which replaces a capital, never is immediately employed to maintain any
but productive hands. It pays the wages of productive labour only. That
which is immediately destined for constituting a revenue, either as profit
or as rent, may maintain indifferently either productive or unproductive
hands.</p>
<p>Whatever part of his stock a man employs as a capital, he always expects
it to be replaced to him with a profit. He employs it, therefore, in
maintaining productive hands only; and after having served in the function
of a capital to him, it constitutes a revenue to them. Whenever he employs
any part of it in maintaining unproductive hands of any kind, that part is
from that moment withdrawn from his capital, and placed in his stock
reserved for immediate consumption.</p>
<p>Unproductive labourers, and those who do not labour at all, are all
maintained by revenue; either, first, by that part of the annual produce
which is originally destined for constituting a revenue to some particular
persons, either as the rent of land, or as the profits of stock; or,
secondly, by that part which, though originally destined for replacing a
capital, and for maintaining productive labourers only, yet when it comes
into their hands, whatever part of it is over and above their necessary
subsistence, may be employed in maintaining indifferently either
productive or unproductive hands. Thus, not only the great landlord or the
rich merchant, but even the common workman, if his wages are considerable,
may maintain a menial servant; or he may sometimes go to a play or a
puppet-show, and so contribute his share towards maintaining one set of
unproductive labourers; or he may pay some taxes, and thus help to
maintain another set, more honourable and useful, indeed, but equally
unproductive. No part of the annual produce, however, which had been
originally destined to replace a capital, is ever directed towards
maintaining unproductive hands, till after it has put into motion its full
complement of productive labour, or all that it could put into motion in
the way in which it was employed. The workman must have earned his wages
by work done, before he can employ any part of them in this manner. That
part, too, is generally but a small one. It is his spare revenue only, of
which productive labourers have seldom a great deal. They generally have
some, however; and in the payment of taxes, the greatness of their number
may compensate, in some measure, the smallness of their contribution. The
rent of land and the profits of stock are everywhere, therefore, the
principal sources from which unproductive hands derive their subsistence.
These are the two sorts of revenue of which the owners have generally most
to spare. They might both maintain indifferently, either productive or
unproductive hands. They seem, however, to have some predilection for the
latter. The expense of a great lord feeds generally more idle than
industrious people. The rich merchant, though with his capital he
maintains industrious people only, yet by his expense, that is, by the
employment of his revenue, he feeds commonly the very same sort as the
great lord.</p>
<p>The proportion, therefore, between the productive and unproductive hands,
depends very much in every country upon the proportion between that part
of the annual produce, which, as soon as it comes either from the ground,
or from the hands of the productive labourers, is destined for replacing a
capital, and that which is destined for constituting a revenue, either as
rent or as profit. This proportion is very different in rich from what it
is in poor countries.</p>
<p>Thus, at present, in the opulent countries of Europe, a very large,
frequently the largest, portion of the produce of the land, is destined
for replacing the capital of the rich and independent farmer; the other
for paying his profits, and the rent of the landlord. But anciently,
during the prevalency of the feudal government, a very small portion of
the produce was sufficient to replace the capital employed in cultivation.
It consisted commonly in a few wretched cattle, maintained altogether by
the spontaneous produce of uncultivated land, and which might, therefore,
be considered as a part of that spontaneous produce. It generally, too,
belonged to the landlord, and was by him advanced to the occupiers of the
land. All the rest of the produce properly belonged to him too, either as
rent for his land, or as profit upon this paltry capital. The occupiers of
land were generally bond-men, whose persons and effects were equally his
property. Those who were not bond-men were tenants at will; and though the
rent which they paid was often nominally little more than a quit-rent, it
really amounted to the whole produce of the land. Their lord could at all
times command their labour in peace and their service in war. Though they
lived at a distance from his house, they were equally dependent upon him
as his retainers who lived in it. But the whole produce of the land
undoubtedly belongs to him, who can dispose of the labour and service of
all those whom it maintains. In the present state of Europe, the share of
the landlord seldom exceeds a third, sometimes not a fourth part of the
whole produce of the land. The rent of land, however, in all the improved
parts of the country, has been tripled and quadrupled since those ancient
times; and this third or fourth part of the annual produce is, it seems,
three or four times greater than the whole had been before. In the
progress of improvement, rent, though it increases in proportion to the
extent, diminishes in proportion to the produce of the land.</p>
<p>In the opulent countries of Europe, great capitals are at present employed
in trade and manufactures. In the ancient state, the little trade that was
stirring, and the few homely and coarse manufactures that were carried on,
required but very small capitals. These, however, must have yielded very
large profits. The rate of interest was nowhere less than ten per cent.
and their profits must have been sufficient to afford this great interest.
At present, the rate of interest, in the improved parts of Europe, is
nowhere higher than six per cent.; and in some of the most improved, it is
so low as four, three, and two per cent. Though that part of the revenue
of the inhabitants which is derived from the profits of stock, is always
much greater in rich than in poor countries, it is because the stock is
much greater; in proportion to the stock, the profits are generally much
less.</p>
<p>That part of the annual produce, therefore, which, as soon as it comes
either from the ground, or from the hands of the productive labourers, is
destined for replacing a capital, is not only much greater in rich than in
poor countries, but bears a much greater proportion to that which is
immediately destined for constituting a revenue either as rent or as
profit. The funds destined for the maintenance of productive labour are
not only much greater in the former than in the latter, but bear a much
greater proportion to those which, though they may be employed to maintain
either productive or unproductive hands, have generally a predilection for
the latter.</p>
<p>The proportion between those different funds necessarily determines in
every country the general character of the inhabitants as to industry or
idleness. We are more industrious than our forefathers, because, in the
present times, the funds destined for the maintenance of industry are much
greater in proportion to those which are likely to be employed in the
maintenance of idleness, than they were two or three centuries ago. Our
ancestors were idle for want of a sufficient encouragement to industry. It
is better, says the proverb, to play for nothing, than to work for
nothing. In mercantile and manufacturing towns, where the inferior ranks
of people are chiefly maintained by the employment of capital, they are in
general industrious, sober, and thriving; as in many English, and in most
Dutch towns. In those towns which are principally supported by the
constant or occasional residence of a court, and in which the inferior
ranks of people are chiefly maintained by the spending of revenue, they
are in general idle, dissolute, and poor; as at Rome, Versailles,
Compeigne, and Fontainbleau. If you except Rouen and Bourdeaux, there is
little trade or industry in any of the parliament towns of France; and the
inferior ranks of people, being chiefly maintained by the expense of the
members of the courts of justice, and of those who come to plead before
them, are in general idle and poor. The great trade of Rouen and Bourdeaux
seems to be altogether the effect of their situation. Rouen is necessarily
the entrepot of almost all the goods which are brought either from foreign
countries, or from the maritime provinces of France, for the consumption
of the great city of Paris. Bourdeaux is, in the same manner, the entrepot
of the wines which grow upon the banks of the Garronne, and of the rivers
which run into it, one of the richest wine countries in the world, and
which seems to produce the wine fittest for exportation, or best suited to
the taste of foreign nations. Such advantageous situations necessarily
attract a great capital by the great employment which they afford it; and
the employment of this capital is the cause of the industry of those two
cities. In the other parliament towns of France, very little more capital
seems to be employed than what is necessary for supplying their own
consumption; that is, little more than the smallest capital which can be
employed in them. The same thing may be said of Paris, Madrid, and Vienna.
Of those three cities, Paris is by far the most industrious, but Paris
itself is the principal market of all the manufactures established at
Paris, and its own consumption is the principal object of all the trade
which it carries on. London, Lisbon, and Copenhagen, are, perhaps, the
only three cities in Europe, which are both the constant residence of a
court, and can at the same time be considered as trading cities, or as
cities which trade not only for their own consumption, but for that of
other cities and countries. The situation of all the three is extremely
advantageous, and naturally fits them to be the entrepots of a great part
of the goods destined for the consumption of distant places. In a city
where a great revenue is spent, to employ with advantage a capital for any
other purpose than for supplying the consumption of that city, is probably
more difficult than in one in which the inferior ranks of people have no
other maintenance but what they derive from the employment of such a
capital. The idleness of the greater part of the people who are maintained
by the expense of revenue, corrupts, it is probable, the industry of those
who ought to be maintained by the employment of capital, and renders it
less advantageous to employ a capital there than in other places. There
was little trade or industry in Edinburgh before the Union. When the
Scotch parliament was no longer to be assembled in it, when it ceased to
be the necessary residence of the principal nobility and gentry of
Scotland, it became a city of some trade and industry. It still continues,
however, to be the residence of the principal courts of justice in
Scotland, of the boards of customs and excise, etc. A considerable
revenue, therefore, still continues to be spent in it. In trade and
industry, it is much inferior to Glasgow, of which the inhabitants are
chiefly maintained by the employment of capital. The inhabitants of a
large village, it has sometimes been observed, after having made
considerable progress in manufactures, have become idle and poor, in
consequence of a great lord's having taken up his residence in their
neighbourhood.</p>
<p>The proportion between capital and revenue, therefore, seems everywhere to
regulate the proportion between industry and idleness Wherever capital
predominates, industry prevails; wherever revenue, idleness. Every
increase or diminution of capital, therefore, naturally tends to increase
or diminish the real quantity of industry, the number of productive hands,
and consequently the exchangeable value of the annual produce of the land
and labour of the country, the real wealth and revenue of all its
inhabitants.</p>
<p>Capitals are increased by parsimony, and diminished by prodigality and
misconduct.</p>
<p>Whatever a person saves from his revenue he adds to his capital, and
either employs it himself in maintaining an additional number of
productive hands, or enables some other person to do so, by lending it to
him for an interest, that is, for a share of the profits. As the capital
of an individual can be increased only by what he saves from his annual
revenue or his annual gains, so the capital of a society, which is the
same with that of all the individuals who compose it, can be increased
only in the same manner.</p>
<p>Parsimony, and not industry, is the immediate cause of the increase of
capital. Industry, indeed, provides the subject which parsimony
accumulates; but whatever industry might acquire, if parsimony did not
save and store up, the capital would never be the greater.</p>
<p>Parsimony, by increasing the fund which is destined for the maintenance of
productive hands, tends to increase the number of those hands whose labour
adds to the value of the subject upon winch it is bestowed. It tends,
therefore, to increase the exchangeable value of the annual produce of the
land and labour of the country. It puts into motion an additional quantity
of industry, which gives an additional value to the annual produce.</p>
<p>What is annually saved, is as regularly consumed as what is annually
spent, and nearly in the same time too: but it is consumed by a different
set of people. That portion of his revenue which a rich man annually
spends, is, in most cases, consumed by idle guests and menial servants,
who leave nothing behind them in return for their consumption. That
portion which he annually saves, as, for the sake of the profit, it is
immediately employed as a capital, is consumed in the same manner, and
nearly in the same time too, but by a different set of people: by
labourers, manufacturers, and artificers, who reproduce, with a profit,
the value of their annual consumption. His revenue, we shall suppose, is
paid him in money. Had he spent the whole, the food, clothing, and
lodging, which the whole could have purchased, would have been distributed
among the former set of people. By saving a part of it, as that part is,
for the sake of the profit, immediately employed as a capital, either by
himself or by some other person, the food, clothing, and lodging, which
may be purchased with it, are necessarily reserved for the latter. The
consumption is the same, but the consumers are different.</p>
<p>By what a frugal man annually saves, he not only affords maintenance to an
additional number of productive hands, for that of the ensuing year, but
like the founder of a public work-house he establishes, as it were, a
perpetual fund for the maintenance of an equal number in all times to
come. The perpetual allotment and destination of this fund, indeed, is not
always guarded by any positive law, by any trust-right or deed of
mortmain. It is always guarded, however, by a very powerful principle, the
plain and evident interest of every individual to whom any share of it
shall ever belong. No part of it can ever afterwards be employed to
maintain any but productive hands, without an evident loss to the person
who thus perverts it from its proper destination.</p>
<p>The prodigal perverts it in this manner: By not confining his expense
within his income, he encroaches upon his capital. Like him who perverts
the revenues of some pious foundation to profane purposes, he pays the
wages of idleness with those funds which the frugality of his forefathers
had, as it were, consecrated to the maintenance of industry. By
diminishing the funds destined for the employment of productive labour, he
necessarily diminishes, so far as it depends upon him, the quantity of
that labour which adds a value to the subject upon which it is bestowed,
and, consequently, the value of the annual produce of the land and labour
of the whole country, the real wealth and revenue of its inhabitants. If
the prodigality of some were not compensated by the frugality of others,
the conduct of every prodigal, by feeding the idle with the bread of the
industrious, would tend not only to beggar himself, but to impoverish his
country.</p>
<p>Though the expense of the prodigal should be altogether in home made, and
no part of it in foreign commodities, its effect upon the productive funds
of the society would still be the same. Every year there would still be a
certain quantity of food and clothing, which ought to have maintained
productive, employed in maintaining unproductive hands. Every year,
therefore, there would still be some diminution in what would otherwise
have been the value of the annual produce of the land and labour of the
country.</p>
<p>This expense, it may be said, indeed, not being in foreign goods, and not
occasioning any exportation of gold and silver, the same quantity of money
would remain in the country as before. But if the quantity of food and
clothing which were thus consumed by unproductive, had been distributed
among productive hands, they would have reproduced, together with a
profit, the full value of their consumption. The same quantity of money
would, in this case, equally have remained in the country, and there
would, besides, have been a reproduction of an equal value of consumable
goods. There would have been two values instead of one.</p>
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />