<p>In further qualification it is to be noted that the leisure class of today
is recruited from those who have been successful in a pecuniary way, and
who, therefore, are presumably endowed with more than an even complement
of the predatory traits. Entrance into the leisure class lies through the
pecuniary employments, and these employments, by selection and adaptation,
act to admit to the upper levels only those lines of descent that are
pecuniarily fit to survive under the predatory test. And so soon as a case
of reversion to non-predatory human nature shows itself on these upper
levels, it is commonly weeded out and thrown back to the lower pecuniary
levels. In order to hold its place in the class, a stock must have the
pecuniary temperament; otherwise its fortune would be dissipated and it
would presently lose caste. Instances of this kind are sufficiently
frequent. The constituency of the leisure class is kept up by a continual
selective process, whereby the individuals and lines of descent that are
eminently fitted for an aggressive pecuniary competition are withdrawn
from the lower classes. In order to reach the upper levels the aspirant
must have, not only a fair average complement of the pecuniary aptitudes,
but he must have these gifts in such an eminent degree as to overcome very
material difficulties that stand in the way of his ascent. Barring
accidents, the nouveaux arriv�s are a picked body.</p>
<p>This process of selective admission has, of course, always been going on;
ever since the fashion of pecuniary emulation set in—which is much
the same as saying, ever since the institution of a leisure class was
first installed. But the precise ground of selection has not always been
the same, and the selective process has therefore not always given the
same results. In the early barbarian, or predatory stage proper, the test
of fitness was prowess, in the naive sense of the word. To gain entrance
to the class, the candidate had to be gifted with clannishness,
massiveness, ferocity, unscrupulousness, and tenacity of purpose. These
were the qualities that counted toward the accumulation and continued
tenure of wealth. The economic basis of the leisure class, then as later,
was the possession of wealth; but the methods of accumulating wealth, and
the gifts required for holding it, have changed in some degree since the
early days of the predatory culture. In consequence of the selective
process the dominant traits of the early barbarian leisure class were bold
aggression, an alert sense of status, and a free resort to fraud. The
members of the class held their place by tenure of prowess. In the later
barbarian culture society attained settled methods of acquisition and
possession under the quasi-peaceable regime of status. Simple aggression
and unrestrained violence in great measure gave place to shrewd practice
and chicanery, as the best approved method of accumulating wealth. A
different range of aptitudes and propensities would then be conserved in
the leisure class. Masterful aggression, and the correlative massiveness,
together with a ruthlessly consistent sense of status, would still count
among the most splendid traits of the class. These have remained in our
traditions as the typical "aristocratic virtues." But with these were
associated an increasing complement of the less obtrusive pecuniary
virtues; such as providence, prudence, and chicanery. As time has gone on,
and the modern peaceable stage of pecuniary culture has been approached,
the last-named range of aptitudes and habits has gained in relative
effectiveness for pecuniary ends, and they have counted for relatively
more in the selective process under which admission is gained and place is
held in the leisure class.</p>
<p>The ground of selection has changed, until the aptitudes which now qualify
for admission to the class are the pecuniary aptitudes only. What remains
of the predatory barbarian traits is the tenacity of purpose or
consistency of aim which distinguished the successful predatory barbarian
from the peaceable savage whom he supplanted. But this trait can not be
said characteristically to distinguish the pecuniarily successful
upper-class man from the rank and file of the industrial classes. The
training and the selection to which the latter are exposed in modern
industrial life give a similarly decisive weight to this trait. Tenacity
of purpose may rather be said to distinguish both these classes from two
others; the shiftless ne'er do-well and the lower-class delinquent. In
point of natural endowment the pecuniary man compares with the delinquent
in much the same way as the industrial man compares with the good-natured
shiftless dependent. The ideal pecuniary man is like the ideal delinquent
in his unscrupulous conversion of goods and persons to his own ends, and
in a callous disregard of the feelings and wishes of others and of the
remoter effects of his actions; but he is unlike him in possessing a
keener sense of status, and in working more consistently and farsightedly
to a remoter end. The kinship of the two types of temperament is further
shown in a proclivity to "sport" and gambling, and a relish of aimless
emulation. The ideal pecuniary man also shows a curious kinship with the
delinquent in one of the concomitant variations of the predatory human
nature. The delinquent is very commonly of a superstitious habit of mind;
he is a great believer in luck, spells, divination and destiny, and in
omens and shamanistic ceremony. Where circumstances are favorable, this
proclivity is apt to express itself in a certain servile devotional fervor
and a punctilious attention to devout observances; it may perhaps be
better characterized as devoutness than as religion. At this point the
temperament of the delinquent has more in common with the pecuniary and
leisure classes than with the industrial man or with the class of
shiftless dependents.</p>
<p>Life in a modern industrial community, or in other words life under the
pecuniary culture, acts by a process of selection to develop and conserve
a certain range of aptitudes and propensities. The present tendency of
this selective process is not simply a reversion to a given, immutable
ethnic type. It tends rather to a modification of human nature differing
in some respects from any of the types or variants transmitted out of the
past. The objective point of the evolution is not a single one. The
temperament which the evolution acts to establish as normal differs from
any one of the archaic variants of human nature in its greater stability
of aim—greater singleness of purpose and greater persistence in
effort. So far as concerns economic theory, the objective point of the
selective process is on the whole single to this extent; although there
are minor tendencies of considerable importance diverging from this line
of development. But apart from this general trend the line of development
is not single. As concerns economic theory, the development in other
respects runs on two divergent lines. So far as regards the selective
conservation of capacities or aptitudes in individuals, these two lines
may be called the pecuniary and the industrial. As regards the
conservation of propensities, spiritual attitude, or animus, the two may
be called the invidious or self-regarding and the non-invidious or
economical. As regards the intellectual or cognitive bent of the two
directions of growth, the former may be characterized as the personal
standpoint, of conation, qualitative relation, status, or worth; the
latter as the impersonal standpoint, of sequence, quantitative relation,
mechanical efficiency, or use.</p>
<p>The pecuniary employments call into action chiefly the former of these two
ranges of aptitudes and propensities, and act selectively to conserve them
in the population. The industrial employments, on the other hand, chiefly
exercise the latter range, and act to conserve them. An exhaustive
psychological analysis will show that each of these two ranges of
aptitudes and propensities is but the multiform expression of a given
temperamental bent. By force of the unity or singleness of the individual,
the aptitudes, animus, and interests comprised in the first-named range
belong together as expressions of a given variant of human nature. The
like is true of the latter range. The two may be conceived as alternative
directions of human life, in such a way that a given individual inclines
more or less consistently to the one or the other. The tendency of the
pecuniary life is, in a general way, to conserve the barbarian
temperament, but with the substitution of fraud and prudence, or
administrative ability, in place of that predilection for physical damage
that characterizes the early barbarian. This substitution of chicanery in
place of devastation takes place only in an uncertain degree. Within the
pecuniary employments the selective action runs pretty consistently in
this direction, but the discipline of pecuniary life, outside the
competition for gain, does not work consistently to the same effect. The
discipline of modern life in the consumption of time and goods does not
act unequivocally to eliminate the aristocratic virtues or to foster the
bourgeois virtues. The conventional scheme of decent living calls for a
considerable exercise of the earlier barbarian traits. Some details of
this traditional scheme of life, bearing on this point, have been noticed
in earlier chapters under the head of leisure, and further details will be
shown in later chapters.</p>
<p>From what has been said, it appears that the leisure-class life and the
leisure-class scheme of life should further the conservation of the
barbarian temperament; chiefly of the quasi-peaceable, or bourgeois,
variant, but also in some measure of the predatory variant. In the absence
of disturbing factors, therefore, it should be possible to trace a
difference of temperament between the classes of society. The aristocratic
and the bourgeois virtues—that is to say the destructive and
pecuniary traits—should be found chiefly among the upper classes,
and the industrial virtues—that is to say the peaceable traits—chiefly
among the classes given to mechanical industry.</p>
<p>In a general and uncertain way this holds true, but the test is not so
readily applied nor so conclusive as might be wished. There are several
assignable reasons for its partial failure. All classes are in a measure
engaged in the pecuniary struggle, and in all classes the possession of
the pecuniary traits counts towards the success and survival of the
individual. Wherever the pecuniary culture prevails, the selective process
by which men's habits of thought are shaped, and by which the survival of
rival lines of descent is decided, proceeds proximately on the basis of
fitness for acquisition. Consequently, if it were not for the fact that
pecuniary efficiency is on the whole incompatible with industrial
efficiency, the selective action of all occupations would tend to the
unmitigated dominance of the pecuniary temperament. The result would be
the installation of what has been known as the "economic man," as the
normal and definitive type of human nature. But the "economic man," whose
only interest is the self-regarding one and whose only human trait is
prudence is useless for the purposes of modern industry.</p>
<p>The modern industry requires an impersonal, non-invidious interest in the
work in hand. Without this the elaborate processes of industry would be
impossible, and would, indeed, never have been conceived. This interest in
work differentiates the workman from the criminal on the one hand, and
from the captain of industry on the other. Since work must be done in
order to the continued life of the community, there results a qualified
selection favoring the spiritual aptitude for work, within a certain range
of occupations. This much, however, is to be conceded, that even within
the industrial occupations the selective elimination of the pecuniary
traits is an uncertain process, and that there is consequently an
appreciable survival of the barbarian temperament even within these
occupations. On this account there is at present no broad distinction in
this respect between the leisure-class character and the character of the
common run of the population.</p>
<p>The whole question as to a class distinction in respect to spiritual
make-up is also obscured by the presence, in all classes of society, of
acquired habits of life that closely simulate inherited traits and at the
same time act to develop in the entire body of the population the traits
which they simulate. These acquired habits, or assumed traits of
character, are most commonly of an aristocratic cast. The prescriptive
position of the leisure class as the exemplar of reputability has imposed
many features of the leisure-class theory of life upon the lower classes;
with the result that there goes on, always and throughout society, a more
or less persistent cultivation of these aristocratic traits. On this
ground also these traits have a better chance of survival among the body
of the people than would be the case if it were not for the precept and
example of the leisure class. As one channel, and an important one,
through which this transfusion of aristocratic views of life, and
consequently more or less archaic traits of character goes on, may be
mentioned the class of domestic servants. These have their notions of what
is good and beautiful shaped by contact with the master class and carry
the preconceptions so acquired back among their low-born equals, and so
disseminate the higher ideals abroad through the community without the
loss of time which this dissemination might otherwise suffer. The saying
"Like master, like man," has a greater significance than is commonly
appreciated for the rapid popular acceptance of many elements of
upper-class culture.</p>
<p>There is also a further range of facts that go to lessen class differences
as regards the survival of the pecuniary virtues. The pecuniary struggle
produces an underfed class, of large proportions. This underfeeding
consists in a deficiency of the necessaries of life or of the necessaries
of a decent expenditure. In either case the result is a closely enforced
struggle for the means with which to meet the daily needs; whether it be
the physical or the higher needs. The strain of self-assertion against
odds takes up the whole energy of the individual; he bends his efforts to
compass his own invidious ends alone, and becomes continually more
narrowly self-seeking. The industrial traits in this way tend to
obsolescence through disuse. Indirectly, therefore, by imposing a scheme
of pecuniary decency and by withdrawing as much as may be of the means of
life from the lower classes, the institution of a leisure class acts to
conserve the pecuniary traits in the body of the population. The result is
an assimilation of the lower classes to the type of human nature that
belongs primarily to the upper classes only. It appears, therefore, that
there is no wide difference in temperament between the upper and the lower
classes; but it appears also that the absence of such a difference is in
good part due to the prescriptive example of the leisure class and to the
popular acceptance of those broad principles of conspicuous waste and
pecuniary emulation on which the institution of a leisure class rests. The
institution acts to lower the industrial efficiency of the community and
retard the adaptation of human nature to the exigencies of modern
industrial life. It affects the prevalent or effective human nature in a
conservative direction, (1) by direct transmission of archaic traits,
through inheritance within the class and wherever the leisure-class blood
is transfused outside the class, and (2) by conserving and fortifying the
traditions of the archaic regime, and so making the chances of survival of
barbarian traits greater also outside the range of transfusion of
leisure-class blood.</p>
<p>But little if anything has been done towards collecting or digesting data
that are of special significance for the question of survival or
elimination of traits in the modern populations. Little of a tangible
character can therefore be offered in support of the view here taken,
beyond a discursive review of such everyday facts as lie ready to hand.
Such a recital can scarcely avoid being commonplace and tedious, but for
all that it seems necessary to the completeness of the argument, even in
the meager outline in which it is here attempted. A degree of indulgence
may therefore fairly be bespoken for the succeeding chapters, which offer
a fragmentary recital of this kind.</p>
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />