<h2>CHAPTER 9</h2>
<h3>THE LAW OF DIMINISHING RETURNS</h3>
<h4>§ I. DEFINITION OF THE CONCEPT OF (ECONOMIC) DIMINISHING RETURNS</h4>
<div class="sidenote">Economic agents contain uses to be obtained only with
progressive difficulty</div>
<p>1. <i>The phrase "diminishing returns of industrial agents" is the
expression of the fact that there is an elastic limit to the utility any
indirect good can afford within a given time.</i> Successive attempts to
get additional services from a thing are usually in part successful, but
each additional service is gained with more difficulty, or a smaller
added service is gained for an equal expenditure of materials or effort.
A book stands many hours untouched on the shelves of the library; but
if, as often happens, two or more persons wish to use it at the same
hour, time and energy are wasted. The book has a potential use during
the twenty-four hours, but all this can be secured only at the cost of
the greatest inconvenience. The greatest net uses, therefore, are seen
to be to the first user and in the first hour, for these uses cost the
least time and trouble. If the members of a family will take turns, one
chair will serve for all of them; but if all are to be able to sit down
together, a chair must be provided for each. Often it will happen that
only one chair is in use, the other nine chairs being valued only for
their potential uses. I knew two young men who owned a dress-coat in
partnership, and as they had different evenings free from business all
went well until both were invited to a reception which both were very
eager to attend.</p>
<p><span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_62" id="Page_62">[Pg 62]</SPAN></span></p>
<div class="sidenote">This is true of all classes of agents</div>
<p>Illustrations of this principle may be drawn from every class of durable
goods. The example generally given is that of a field used for
agriculture. It was long ago seen that a larger crop could usually be
obtained on the same area, only with greater effort or expenditure; but
this fact has been thought to be peculiar to the use of land. The
examples given above have been purposely chosen from very different
fields, to show that the truth is a general one: a good that affords a
given service can be made to increase that service, ordinarily, only on
condition that men put forth greater effort, or sacrifice more goods.</p>
<p>The decreased utility is most clearly seen in the diminished effect
which other agents produce when used in connection with the thing. When
several are trying to use the same book, and are wasting time trying to
get it, we often say their study hours are less fruitful because of the
poor library facilities. Again, we speak either of the diminished
returns of the field, or of the labor applied to the field. Either the
particular thing is said to show diminished returns or the other
coöperating agents are said to show them.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Decreasing technical effectiveness of material things</div>
<p>2. <i>As the agents used in connection with a fixed amount of any other
agent (for mechanical, chemical, physiological, psychological, and other
purposes) increase, their objective effectiveness after a given point
decreases.</i> Objective or technical effectiveness means effectiveness
independent of the thought or estimate of men. It is not the
effectiveness to produce a feeling in men, but to produce results on the
material world. In a mechanism, if one part is increased without
increasing the other parts, a point is reached where it does not add to
the result. If in the building of a bridge the weight of the floor is
increased beyond a certain point, the rest of the bridge being left
unchanged, the bridge is weakened instead of strengthened. If the weight
of the iron in the framework is increased beyond a certain point without
strengthening the piers, the structure is weakened. If the pier is
greatly enlarged, the bridge may not be weakened, but there is an utter
waste of material and effort, and perhaps<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_63" id="Page_63">[Pg 63]</SPAN></span> the main purpose of the
bridge is defeated by the damming up of the stream. A bicycle frame,
like a chain, is no stronger than its weakest part. If the strength of
all parts of the wheel and frame is in equal proportion to the strain
they must bear, added weight to any single part weakens the whole
machine. The development of the modern type of bicycle, by many
experiments, is a good example of the adjustment of materials according
to the principle of technical efficiency.</p>
<p>A variation of the same principle is seen in chemical combinations.
Exact proportions of materials must be used to get a certain result.
Increase of one ingredient will not increase the desired product. Either
the added part is rejected, does not enter at all into the compound, or
it unites to form another and different product.</p>
<p>That the same principle holds good of the psychological effects of
things, we have already fully recognized in discussing wants and
marginal utility. A given amount of a good will affect the senses in a
pleasurable way, but an increase in the amount will not cause a
proportional addition to pleasure of sight, sound, or smell. On the
contrary, such an increase may defeat the object entirely. Here we are
at the threshold of the economic problem, for we have touched on
"feeling."</p>
<div class="sidenote">Economic diminishing returns relate to value</div>
<p>3. <i>The idea of economic diminishing returns arises when man recognizes
these technical facts and their relation to gratification, in his use of
a limited supply of indirect agents.</i> All economy begins with scarcity.
The varying effects produced by different agents therefore require to be
studied or the sum or direct goods of enjoyment will not be as great as
is possible. Waste will take place. A bridge will have its maximum use
with a minimum outlay when the parts are in a certain proportion. Beyond
that point, the increase of any part may add something to the usefulness
of the bridge, but the agents must be taken from some other and greater
use.</p>
<p><span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_64" id="Page_64">[Pg 64]</SPAN></span></p>
<p>The thought of economic diminishing returns always has reference to
value. If a particular kind and amount of a certain material is used in
varying combinations with other agents, the value of the added product
will not always be in the same proportion to the value of the added
agent. The bridge-builder must consider not only what the added material
will add to strength, but what it will cost, and whether the result will
justify this expense. So the economic problem of diminishing returns is
more complicated than the mechanical one, for it contains not only the
technical but other factors.</p>
<div class="sidenote">The marginal utility in goods</div>
<p>If the value of the product increases less rapidly than the cost of the
agents successively added to secure it, a point must at length be
reached where the value of the added agents and of the additional
product just balance; this is called the point of marginal utility.</p>
<p>If a certain value in labor, fertilizer, or material, be applied to an
acre of land, it may be more than recovered in the value of the product.
Further applications give a product increased not in equal proportion to
the former yield, and so on till the value of the last-added agent just
balances that of the added product. This is the best adjustment
possible, and beyond this point there will be a deficit in value. Just
where the equilibrium is found at any time is the margin of cultivation.</p>
<p>The term "cultivation" is taken from agriculture but must be understood
in the broader sense of utilization, as the principle is not confined to
the case of land or agriculture, but applies as well to the use of
furniture, books, clothing, horses, or any other indirect agents.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Meaning of intensive margin of utilization</div>
<div class="sidenote">The extensive margin of utilization</div>
<p>4. <i>There are two margins, the intensive and the extensive.</i> The margin
of utilization in the case of a single piece of wealth is called the
intensive margin. Any form of indirect wealth, anything kept to use, may
be considered as containing a series of uses. Using one thing more and
more while uniting other things with it, is using it more intensively.</p>
<p><span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_65" id="Page_65">[Pg 65]</SPAN></span></p>
<p>Getting more use out of the book by effort, out of the farm by applying
more fertilizer, out of the house by putting more people into it, is
intensive utilization. The earlier uses come easily, naturally; the
later ones are gotten with increasing difficulty.</p>
<p>When a number of agents are of different qualities, the point between
the one last used and the next unused is the extensive margin of
utilization. The best agents that are available are naturally used
first, but as they are more intensively used there is increasing
inconvenience. Then recourse must be made to the inferior agents, whose
first uses, however, are greater than the later, intensive uses, of the
better grades. When the step is made to the use of agents that were
before unused because inferior, it is extending the margin of
utilization. The intensive margin of use is in the particular thing; the
extensive margin of use lies outside of this.</p>
<div class="figcenter"> <ANTIMG src="images/i65.jpg" width-obs="500" height-obs="471" alt="" /> <span class="caption"><i>Extensive Grades of Uses</i></span></div>
<p>The relation of the two margins may be shown in a simple diagram. Let
the better grades of indirect agents be represented by longer
rectangles, the upper parts of which represent the more accessible, more
easily secured utilities. Each agent consists of many strata of uses.
The best uses are grades a, b, and c, in M; but after M has been
utilized intensively<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_66" id="Page_66">[Pg 66]</SPAN></span> down to d, N will begin to be utilized at its
highest point. When utilization goes down to f, O comes into use, and so
on. Therefore it will be seen that until the intensive margin takes in
d, M is on the extreme margin of utilization, and N is just outside it;
when the intensive margin falls to g and h, P is inside the extensive
margin, and Q is just outside.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Equilibrium of the two margins</div>
<p>The marginal utility or effectiveness of added agents tends to be equal
on the intensive and the extensive margins. This is simply a case of the
substitution of goods in the use of indirect agents. If the value of the
added product in the use of a particular good decreases, a point finally
is reached where it is better to transfer the outlay to another agent,
to change from intensive to extensive utilization, to go over to the use
of another field or of another machine not so good. The effectiveness of
the labor or capital that men have to apply is being compared constantly
in the two cases, and to the extent that this comparison is perfect the
effectiveness of the agents tends to be equal on the margin in the two
applications.</p>
<h4>§ II. OTHER MEANINGS OF THE PHRASE "DIMINISHING RETURNS"</h4>
<div class="sidenote">Does not mean declining prosperity</div>
<p>1. <i>The phrase diminishing returns is sometimes taken as meaning merely
a decrease in prosperity.</i> Many ideas are connected with this phrase. It
is not self-explanatory. It suggests various thoughts according to
context and these have not failed to give rise to different uses. The
student must be cautious if he is to think clearly about it. If
population declines, or industry changes from one place to another, or
from one kind of goods to another, it is sometimes said that returns are
diminishing in the deserted district.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Nor exhaustion of the soil</div>
<p>2. <i>A more common misuse of the term is to apply it to the exhaustion of
the soil.</i> If the soil of a district has been robbed of its fertile
qualities and smaller crops are raised<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_67" id="Page_67">[Pg 67]</SPAN></span> than was the case fifty years
before, it is said to be a case of of the increased difficulty in the
extraction of natural stores in mining. The veins near the surface being
mined first, later the galleries must be cut deeper and greater expense
incurred to get the stores. But the conditions here are very different
from those we have considered under diminishing returns. Mines are used
not under the renting contract, but under the royalty contract, which
permits and contemplates a progressive using up of the limited stores of
natural resources.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Fallacious contract between manufacture and agriculture</div>
<div class="sidenote">All industries if limited as to one factor, as area, show
diminishing returns</div>
<p>3. <i>Manufactures are often said to show increasing returns in contrast
with agriculture as an industry of decreasing returns.</i> There is here an
inconsistent shifting of thought. Agriculture is thought of as limited
to a certain area of ground, whereon evidently diminishing returns will
take place. But the fixed limit of ground-space is not thought of in
connection with manufactures. Taking the same view of manufactures,
commerce, education, etc., that is, assuming each industry to be
confined to limited area of ground, each is seen to be subject to
diminishing returns. Some ground-space is one of the essentials to carry
on any business. If the attempt is made to accumulate a large library in
one small room, a point is reached where much energy is wasted in trying
to find the books. In a university the psychical product, education, may
be limited by the need of space. The school-room, laboratory, or college
class-room could be used at midnight, it is true, but not conveniently;
and as students increase, buildings must be added. The same is true of
any industry. We cannot conveniently increase the business of a
lumber-yard without a larger yard-space, or of a factory without a
larger floor-space. But the added space may be gotten by spreading
horizontally or piling up perpendicularly. A ten-story building on an
acre lot represents ten acres of floor-space. Putting up higher
buildings is an expansion in area by the more intensive utilization of
the land. Devices like elevators, and more compact appliances,<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_68" id="Page_68">[Pg 68]</SPAN></span> make
possible an increasing business in manufacture, trade, or commerce upon
the same area of land. All industries, if looked at consistently from
this standpoint, are subject to the same condition, though it is true
this will make itself felt in varying degrees in different lines of
industry. In agriculture some similar devices are possible by the use of
greenhouses, but it is true that in it, on account of the need of sun,
light, and air, the limits of space are more quickly felt, and are less
elastic than in most other industries. The difference, however, is one
of degree, and not of kind. Higher factories, larger stores, enable
manufacturers to adapt themselves to the law as applied to the surface
of land, but not to escape its operations. Neither the law of
gravitation nor the law of diminishing returns is violated or broken
when materials are lifted to build the upper stories. Both "laws" are at
work, even when the building is rising from the ground. Men are merely
adapting their conduct to the conditions imposed by gravitation and
diminishing returns.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Confused with the question of large production</div>
<p>Manufactures usually are thought of as enlarging by increase of the
amount of capital employed, without limitation as to the area covered.
But even here a limit is reached in the amount of capital that can be
employed at any one location because of the difficulty of widening the
market. The question, however, is one of the advantages of large
production with large capital, not of the increasing use of a limited
area of land. If manufactures and agriculture are to be compared with
reference to their economic nature, it is essential to clear thinking
that both be looked at with reference to the same conditions, and from
the same point of view.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Technical confused with historical diminishing returns</div>
<p>4. <i>Technical diminishing returns are often confused with historical
diminishing returns.</i> The principle of technical diminishing returns is
that at any given moment the uses obtainable from any indirect agent
cannot be indefinitely increased without increasing difficulty.
Historical diminishing returns occur when, in fact, human effort is less
bountifully<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_69" id="Page_69">[Pg 69]</SPAN></span> rewarded in a later period than in an earlier one. If
to-day a day's labor in agriculture produced less than fifty years ago,
historical diminishing returns would have occurred. In fact, labor is
more bountifully rewarded in agriculture than fifty years ago, yet it is
true to-day that there are few fields or appliances which, if used more
intensively with the prevailing prices of labor and material, would not
show a diminishing return to the additional capital applied. Therefore,
in the historical sense, increasing returns have prevailed, yet at every
moment it has been necessary to apply resources under the guidance of
the principle of diminishing returns.</p>
<h4>§ III. DEVELOPMENT OF THE CONCEPT OF DIMINISHING RETURNS</h4>
<div class="sidenote">Recognition of diminishing returns to land</div>
<p>1. <i>The law of "diminishing returns" was first recognized and expressed
with reference to the use of land in agriculture.</i> There are several
evident reasons why this occurred. It is obvious to every farmer and
gardener that he cannot indefinitely increase his crop, that two men
cannot always produce twice as much as one man, and that in general the
product does not always vary in proportion to the labor and materials
applied. Moreover, the food supply is a fundamental factor in industry
and in the welfare of states. The limit to the supply of food on a given
area, cultivated by a given method, early appeared and became a serious
practical problem.</p>
<p>The circumstances in Europe in the eighteenth century drew attention to
the subject. Population was increasing, and the pressure for food was
strong. While all the forms of industry most common in cities were
increasing, and the wealth of the cities was growing, poverty was
increasing among the peasantry. Especially was this true in England
during the Napoleonic wars, 1793-1815, owing to exceptional conditions.
The food-supply from abroad was cut off, and<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_70" id="Page_70">[Pg 70]</SPAN></span> when the English farmers,
tempted by the high prices, took poorer land into cultivation, and
sought to get larger crops from their older fields, a great
object-lesson was presented on the principle of diminishing returns in
agriculture.</p>
<div class="sidenote">This confused with historical diminishing returns</div>
<p>2. <i>This truth of diminishing returns in agriculture was confused with
the thought of historical diminishing returns.</i> Circumstances of the
time led to the belief that because of lack of food misery must continue
among the masses of men. It was thought inevitable that the population
would continue to increase and food become more scarce. The idea of
diminishing returns became thus a prophecy of what would happen, a
social philosophy, that affected the thought of men on every practical
social question.</p>
<div class="sidenote">The principle applies to land in all of its uses</div>
<p>3. <i>The application of the principle of diminishing returns was soon
broadened to include land in other than agricultural uses.</i> This was a
natural and inevitable extension of the thought. It was evident that an
unlimited use could not be made of a limited area of land, in any
industry whatever. There is no explanation of rent of business sites,
residences, lots, wharves, waterfalls, etc., unless account is taken of
diminishing returns. If it were possible to do an unlimited amount of
business upon a limited area of land, it would never get more scarce and
could never rise in value. The idea of diminishing returns came
properly, therefore, to be applied to land in all its uses. It is true,
however, that the relatively large areas needed in agriculture make the
phenomenon of diminishing returns much more striking in it than in most
other industries.</p>
<div class="sidenote">And to all indirect agents</div>
<p>4. "Diminishing returns" should be broadly applied to all wealth having
indirect uses. The argument for this view may take both a negative and a
positive form. Why should we say that the principle applies to land and
not to cases of other industrial agents? Why in the case of a waterfall
and not in the case of the water-wheel? Why in the case of the field and
not in the case of the trees in the<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_71" id="Page_71">[Pg 71]</SPAN></span> field? Are they not all scarce and
desirable goods yielding a limited supply of uses?</p>
<p>Positively it can be argued that the concept of diminishing returns is
indispensable to a reasonable explanation of the value of any indirect
agents. Anything that could afford an infinite series of uses at once
would be an infinite supply. If an infinite number of uses could be
gotten out of one hammer in all places at once, it would pound all the
nails in the world. One wagon, one acre of land, one ax, one book of
each kind, would serve for all men, and duplicates would be valueless.
But in the case of every material thing there is a limit of convenient
and economic use.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Diminishing returns related to diminishing gratification</div>
<p>5. <i>Diminishing returns of indirect agents is a special case of the
universal law of the diminishing utility of goods.</i> Diminishing returns
have to do with indirect goods, while diminishing gratification has to
do with direct or consumption goods. They are two species or aspects of
the same general principle. If the supply of certain indirect agents is
increased, thereby increasing consumption goods, the utility of the
indirect agents per unit diminishes. In such a case a diminishing return
is the reflection, back to the indirect good, of the diminishing utility
of the direct goods it helps to secure. Any indirect agent, added to a
fixed amount of other agents with which it is technically used, is
credited with a diminished utility, just as an additional supply of
enjoyable goods, coming to meet a fixed demand, falls in value.</p>
<p>The concept of technical diminishing returns has reference to a limited
period of time. Though a definite agent may have bound up in it a long
series of uses, these cannot be secured at the moment. If a rent-bearer,
such as a fruit-tree, were permanent, and men could wait through
eternity for its yield, they would get an infinite yield of fruit. But
in any finite period, there can be only a limited yield.</p>
<p><span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_72" id="Page_72">[Pg 72]</SPAN></span></p>
<div class="sidenote">The basal law of economics</div>
<p>The concept of diminishing returns is one aspect of the great economic
law of proportionality, that is, it is one expression of the
fundamental, axiomatic truth, that there is a best or proper adjustment
of means and ends. It is, therefore, the central and essential thought
in political economy. On it depend all important conclusions with
reference to the value of indirect goods. Out of it grow the important
economic theories of rent and capitalization.</p>
<hr class="chap" />
<p><span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_73" id="Page_73">[Pg 73]</SPAN></span></p>
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />