<h2>CHAPTER 53</h2>
<h3>PUBLIC OWNERSHIP OF INDUSTRY</h3>
<h4>§ I. EXAMPLES OF PUBLIC OWNERSHIP</h4>
<div class="sidenote">The kinds of political units</div>
<p>1. <i>Local political units generally acquire only industries whose
products must be used in the place where produced.</i> The word industry is
used here in a broad sense, including agents of psychic income not
usually so classed, such as public parks. The grouping of publicly owned
industries according to the size and importance of the political units
cannot be exact, because some classes of industries are owned by several
kinds of political units. Yet, especially with application to American
conditions, an approximate classification may be made on this principle.
Federal states consist of three main groups of political units:
national, provincial, and local. Provincial units are the largest
subdivisions, as the American "states," or commonwealths, the German
states, and the provinces in other countries. The term local political
unit is more complex and may mean county, township, village, city, and
school or sanitary district; but most of what is to be said of local
ownership refers to cities or to incorporated villages.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Municipal ownership of parks, libraries, &c.</div>
<div class="sidenote">Of bridges, markets, waterworks, &c.</div>
<p>Nearly all public parks and recreation grounds are owned by cities. As
population has become more dense, private yards of any extent become
impossible, in cities, for all but the wealthy. Public ownership of
parks insures recreation grounds to the common man in the most
economical way. Of late the movement for large and small public parks
and playgrounds has gone on rapidly in American cities. Related<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_515" id="Page_515">[Pg 515]</SPAN></span> to
parks are public baths, public libraries, art collections, museums,
zoölogical gardens, etc. Some have declared that such a policy stops
little short of a paralyzing socialism for the masses. Reason and
experience fail to reveal any such danger so long as the things supplied
gratify the higher tastes—as art, music, literature, innocent social
recreation. Not until the necessities of life, as bread, clothing, and
houses, are supplied, is encouragement given to the increase of
improvident families and to the breaking down of independent character.
The means of local communication—streets, roads, bridges—were once
owned largely by private citizens. Here and there still are found toll
roads and toll bridges built under charters granted a century ago, but
tolls on public thoroughfares are for the most part abolished. A public
market, where the producer from the farm and the city consumer can meet,
is an old institution that is now being established anew in many cities.
The providing of apparatus for extinguishing fires is always a public
duty; the conveyance of waste water is increasingly a public function;
and the supply of pure water, while often a private enterprise in
villages, and sometimes in large cities, is increasingly undertaken by
public agencies. Public ownership of gas and electric lighting is less
common, as the utility supplied is not so essential and the industry is
somewhat less subject to monopoly; but the difference is one of degree
only. Street-railroads are often under public ownership in Europe; but
there has thus far been no case of the kind in the United States, and
only one in Canada.</p>
<div class="sidenote">American failures in state industry</div>
<p>2. <i>The American state owns and conducts industries mainly whose
products have a wider territorial use.</i> The American commonwealth has
retired from some fields where once it was engaged in industry. Students
of American history know that between the years 1830 and 1840 some
states engaged largely, even wildly, in the building of canals and
undertook to construct railroads, to start banks, and to engage in other
enterprises. The undertaking of these industries<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_516" id="Page_516">[Pg 516]</SPAN></span> was determined often
by political and by selfish local interests, and their operation often
was wasteful. A few enterprises succeeded, the most notable of these
being the Erie Canal in New York. The unsuccessful ones remained
worthless property in the hands of the state or were sold to private
companies, as in the case of the Pennsylvania railroad. This reckless
state enterprise was a bitter lesson in public ownership, and even after
seventy-five years is not without effect on public opinion. For a long
time no proposal for public ownership could have a fair hearing in
America. But railroads and canals are publicly owned, and more or less
successfully operated, in many foreign countries, as in Prussia and
other German states, in Switzerland, and in the new states of Australia.</p>
<div class="sidenote">State ownership of various kinds</div>
<p>There has been recently a rise of interest in forestry in America. This
is especially likely to be a state enterprise wherever the forest tracts
are entirely within the limits of the state, as is the case of the
Adirondacks in New York. Most of the forests in Germany are either
communal or state-owned. The schools, a great industry for turning out a
product of public utility, are largely conducted by the American state
and by local units rather than by the nation or by private enterprise.
The state encourages researches in the arts and sciences, and gives
technical training. A variety of minor enterprises have been undertaken
by states to supply salt, phosphate, banking facilities, even some
manufactures. In the prisons and public institutions, states, such as
New York, that have adopted the system of labor on public account engage
in agriculture and manufacturing on a large scale, the products,
amounting to millions of dollars annually, being used almost entirely by
public agencies.</p>
<div class="sidenote">National ownership of various kinds</div>
<p>3. <i>The nation owns and controls many industries of the widest use and
most general interest.</i> Some industries grow out of the political needs
of government. Established as a means of communication with military
outposts, the post became a convenient means of communication for
merchants<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_517" id="Page_517">[Pg 517]</SPAN></span> and other citizens and grew into a great economic
institution. In most countries the telegraph is publicly owned and has
been annexed to the post, to which it is very closely related in
purpose. The national improvements connected with rivers and harbors
were first political—that is, they were for the use of the governmental
navy; they became, secondly, commercial—for the free use of all
citizens engaged in trade; and they continue to unite these two
characters. Forestry is most largely undertaken in this country by the
national government, doubtless because the large forest areas in the
West extend over state boundaries, and because large tracts of public
lands were still unsold at the time public attention was attracted to
the subject. Since 1890, the policy of reserving great areas for
forests, and picturesque districts for national parks, has developed
greatly. In some countries mines are thought to be peculiarly fitted for
national ownership and control. In Germany, the state owns some coal,
salt, and other mines. Coinage and banking are everywhere looked upon as
a function of sovereignty, and yet it is no more necessary for a nation
to own its own mint in order to control the monetary system than for it
to print the bank-notes in order to regulate their issue. The American
government has its own printing office and therewith its share of
troubles with organized labor. The fish commission, and the various
branches of the department, coöperate with private industry in many
ways. In Germany, compulsory insurance is provided for the workingman.
This hasty survey suggests that the industries undertaken by government
are both varied in nature and large in extent, although small in
proportion to the mass of private industry.</p>
<h4>§ II. ECONOMIC ASPECTS OF PUBLIC OWNERSHIP</h4>
<div class="sidenote">The primary need of public ownership</div>
<p>1. <i>Public ownership is primarily to control the essential agencies of
government.</i> A large part of public ownership and activity in industry
develops from political functions.<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_518" id="Page_518">[Pg 518]</SPAN></span> As society evolves, what was
unessential to political life becomes essential. Civilized government
requires the use of a number of material agents. Buildings for
legislative and executive officers, custom-houses, post-offices,
lighthouses, can be rented of private citizens, as post-offices usually
are in small places; but it is obviously economical and convenient in
large cities for the government to own the public buildings. Government
can reduce to a minimum its employment of labor by "farming out" the
taxes, as all countries once did to some extent, and as France continued
to do up to the French Revolution. It is now the settled policy for
government to own or control its essential agencies, but this does not
involve in every case the employment of day-labor direct to clean the
streets, to collect garbage, etc. The more simple political functions
shade off into the economic. To coinage usually are added the issue of
legal-tender notes and certain banking functions; the post carries
packages, transmits money, and in some cases performs the function of a
savings-bank for small amounts. The only open question is as to the
proper limit to this development.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Conflict of public and private interests</div>
<p>2. <i>Public industry expands to supply as free goods many essentials of
good citizenship, and to insure cheaper and more bountiful supplies of
others.</i> It is the ideal of Herbert Spencer and of a small surviving
group of <i>laissez faire</i> philosophers that government should confine
itself exclusively to the most essential political functions, leaving
the economic functions absolutely alone. It should keep the peace,
prevent men from beating and robbing each other, and preserve the
personal liberty of the citizen. They assume that all of the economic
needs will be provided by competition, in the best way humanly possible,
in quantities and at the rate needed. In many cases, however, the
general interest fails to harmonize with that of the individual. The
forest has an immediate utility to the consumers of lumber, and it has
also a diffused utility in its influence on industry, on climate, and on
torrents and floods. Yet, as the private owner cannot<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_519" id="Page_519">[Pg 519]</SPAN></span> control enough of
the forest to affect the climate, and could not sell climate even if he
could affect it, he will cut down the tree whenever he can gain by doing
so. In this situation either government control or government ownership
of forests is essential.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Social economy of some public industry</div>
<p>In some cases the difficulty of private ownership is in the excessive
cost of collecting for the service. The cost of maintaining tollhouses
at short intervals on a turnpike sometimes exceeds the amount collected.
Collection in other cases, as for the service of lighthouses to passing
ships, is impossible. Public industry secures, through the economy of
large production, a cheaper and more efficient service, the benefits and
costs being diffused throughout the community. The benefits of the work
of experiment-stations for agriculture are felt immediately by the
farmers, but are diffused to all citizens. A manufacturer able to keep
his methods secret, or to retain his advantages for a time, can afford
to undertake experiments in his factory, but the farmer seldom can. The
public ownership of parks for the use of all gives a maximum of economy
in the production of the most essential utilities—fresh air, sunshine,
natural beauty, and playgrounds in the midst of crowded populations.
Municipal ownership of waterworks is an extension of the same idea. Not
only because large amounts of water are used by the public, but because
cheap, pure, abundant water is an essential condition to good
citizenship, speculation should in every possible way be eliminated from
this industry.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Monopolistic nature of localized industries</div>
<p>3. <i>Public ownership tends constantly to include the industries of a
monopolistic nature, locally supplying general necessities.</i> This is no
abstract principle; it is merely a statement of what is seen to be
happening. Some industries are of such a nature that they drift
inevitably into monopolistic control. Waterworks, gas, electric
lighting, street-railways, telephone systems, are among these. However
fierce may be the competition for a time, sooner or later either one
company drives out the other or buys it up, or both come<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_520" id="Page_520">[Pg 520]</SPAN></span> to an
agreement by which the public is made to pay higher prices.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Localized production favors monopoly</div>
<p>A feature favoring the growth of monopoly when such industries are left
to private enterprise, is the need to produce and supply the utility at
a given locality. While two street-railways can compete on neighboring
streets, it is physically impossible for two or more to compete on the
same street. Two systems of water-mains or gas-mains can be put down, as
sometimes is done, but this is not only a great economic waste, but the
tearing up of the streets is an intolerable public nuisance. This
difficulty is less marked in the case of telephones and electric
lighting, and some persons still cling to faith in competition to
regulate the rates in those industries; but faith in competition between
water-companies and between gas-companies has been given up by nearly
all students of the subject.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Gains from large production favor monopoly</div>
<p>4. <i>A second feature favoring monopoly in such industries is the marked
advantage of large production in them.</i> These industries are usually
spoken of as "industries of increasing returns." This advantage is
enjoyed in some degree by every enterprise, but it is gradually
neutralized and limited (as has been noted elsewhere). The need to
extend an expensive physical plant to every point where customers are to
be served, and the very much smaller cost per unit of delivering large
amounts of water, gas, electricity, transportation, etc., on the same
street, offered a greater inducement for one competitor to crowd out or
buy out the other at a more than liberal price. Even then, larger net
dividends and correspondingly larger capitalization are secured than
were before possible to both companies combined.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Uniformity of products favors monopoly</div>
<p>5. <i>A third feature favoring monopoly is uniformity in the quality of
the product furnished.</i> It is a general truth that competition is most
persistent where there is the greatest range of choice open to the
customer, and consequently the most individual treatment required in the
enterpriser. An artist, even a storekeeper, attracts about him a body of
patrons<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_521" id="Page_521">[Pg 521]</SPAN></span> who like his product (for the merchant's manner and method of
dealing are a part of the quality of his goods), and who cannot be
tempted away by slight differences in price. Rival companies in the
stage of competition are seen to claim superiority for their particular
goods and to improve their service in every way possible. A new
telephone company, entering where a monopoly has held the field, works
at once a wonderful betterment in rates, courtesy, and service. But as
the product of all competitors attains the highest technical standard
possible at the time, the rivalry is reduced to one of price, and it is
usually a "fight to the finish."</p>
<div class="sidenote">Franchises favor monopoly</div>
<p>6. <i>A fourth feature favoring monopoly in these enterprises is the
necessity of making permanent and exceptional use of the public streets
and alleys.</i> If this right were granted by a general law to every
citizen, this feature would be sufficiently implied in the foregoing
discussion. As it would be intolerable to allow private interests to use
public property in whatever way they wished, the legislative body makes
special grants in such cases in view of the circumstances. Not only is
the legislature (or council, or county board of commissioners, etc.)
induced by the economic difficulties to withhold a charter to a second
company, but it is exposed to the greatest corrupting influences by the
one already established. The knowledge of the opposition to be
encountered in getting a franchise must keep competitors out, even
though monopoly prices are maintained.</p>
<p>In view of these several features, which are so closely related that
they form a common character, more or less fully shared by various
industries, and especially in view of the necessity for the formal
granting to them of peculiar privileges in the form of a public
franchise, the public, in order to protect the general interest, is
forced to undertake an exceptional control of these industries.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Modes of controlling public utilities</div>
<p>7. <i>Several courses are open to the public, acting in its political
capacity, to retain these monopoly advantages for the general welfare.</i>
First, it may do nothing, trusting<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_522" id="Page_522">[Pg 522]</SPAN></span> vainly to competition to regulate
the rate, or consciously leaving the result to be worked out by the
monopoly principle; this is what in most cases has been done in the past
in America. Second, in granting the franchise it may attempt to fix near
cost the charge for the service or product, so that the franchise will
be worth little or nothing. Third, it may leave the rate to be fixed by
the monopoly principle, but charge for the franchise so much that the
value of the monopoly is appropriated into the public treasury. Fourth,
it may have public officials carry on the business, either selling the
product at cost or making monopoly profits that go into the public
treasury. Various combinations of these plans are followed in practice,
the most common plan being the fixing of maximum rates which, with
improved methods, generally become ineffective. It is difficult to fix a
uniform rate that is equitable, because conditions change, and, further,
because a uniform rate must be applied to all parts of the town,
although the cost of service varies greatly. It is difficult to sell the
franchise for near what it is worth, because of the uncertainty, of the
political blackmail, and of the limited number of competent bidders.
There remains only the policy of public ownership to secure the profits
of monopoly to the public, either directly or in a diffused manner.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Economic basis of public ownership</div>
<div class="sidenote">Cost under public or private ownership</div>
<p>8. <i>Public ownership is economically justified when it secures a utility
of widespread consumption, otherwise impossible, or insures the public a
better quality or a lower price.</i> The question of public ownership is
not exclusively an economic question. There are incidental problems,
such as its effects on enterprise and on political integrity, with which
it is not possible here to deal. In the main, however, public ownership
is simply a business proposition which must be justified by its economic
results. In the case of a general social benefit not to be secured
without public ownership, as popular education or the climatic effect of
forests, the only question to answer is whether the utility is worth the
cost. In<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_523" id="Page_523">[Pg 523]</SPAN></span> the case of industries already in private hands, as
waterworks, gas and electric lighting, there is needed, to make a wise
decision possible, a knowledge of the effect a change to public
ownership will have on value. If public officials can furnish some goods
cheaper than they are furnished by private enterprise, it is because of
the wide margin of monopoly profit, not because there is any magic in
public ownership. The same general items of cost must be met. The first
cost of the plant and the annual interest payments are much the same.
Experience shows that, because of political influence, wages are likely
to be higher under public ownership, but salaries of officials are
higher under private ownership. On the whole, public industry in these
respects probably has no advantage. Some items of cost may be less under
public management. Public collection of dues along with taxes is an
advantage not enjoyed by private companies. Several public officials
sometimes share the same office and thus reduce expenses. In small towns
the public electric lighting and waterworks have been operated more
economically under one roof. Public industry does not have to meet the
cost of lobbying and blackmail which are often forced upon private
companies. But the greatest source of saving in public ownership is the
value of monopoly privileges that, under private management, go into
private pockets.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Character of public officials</div>
<div class="sidenote">Limits and effects of public ownership</div>
<p>The temptation to political corruption may be more insistent when a
large force of men is constantly employed, and when large supplies are
constantly purchased, by public officials, but the temptation is not so
strong or so centralized as it is in the granting of franchises to
wealthy corporations. Public industry is weakened by the absence of
certain motives to excellence that are present in private business. The
income of public officials not being dependent on the economy of
management, the spur and motives of competitive industry are lacking. No
social discovery has made individual honesty and civic virtue useless to
good government.</p>
<p>The decision in any specific case is one dependent on local<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_524" id="Page_524">[Pg 524]</SPAN></span> conditions,
and the exact limits of public ownership are not fixed. Industry is
changing so rapidly that new experience is needed each year. The main
outlines of public ownership, however, are now in large part determined.
Some industries do well, others ill, under public management, and
between these lie many debatable cases. Waterworks and probably electric
lighting, because of the comparative simplicity of their operation, are
more suitable for public ownership than are gas-works. No absolute line
divides the one group from the other. But whatever the changes, the
student of the theory of value must never overlook the fact that the
increase of public ownership is altering in manifold ways the prices of
goods, and is reacting also on the production, distribution, and
consumption of incomes.</p>
<hr class="chap" />
<p><span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_525" id="Page_525">[Pg 525]</SPAN></span></p>
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />